Add $14.7 billion (adjusted for inflation)2 to the GDP;
Add 118,000 jobs to the U.S. economy;
Reduce nationwide unemployment by 27,000 persons;
Raise U.S. personal disposable income by an inflation-adjusted $11 billion;
Increase non-residential net capital stock by $25.1 billion and lower the user cost of capital by 0.3 percent;
Leave relative price levels and key interest rates unaffected, in spite of the stimulating effect repeal would have on economic activity; and
Reduce the nation's publicly held debt by $5.7 billion.
The current plan to restore the FETTs in 2011 will substantially curtail these substantial benefits.
How Estate Transfer Taxes affect Economic Behavior
Several studies have found that the federal estate transfer taxes reduce economic growth. For example, in a 1998 study, former DRI/McGraw-Hill economists Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mariana A. McNeill cited three reasons for this overall effect.3
According to these experts, the FETTs:
Cause considerable resources to be diverted away from economically productive activities and toward tax avoidance activities;
Raise the user cost of capital, biasing affected owners of capital toward consumption and away from investment; and
Reduce labor force participation.4
Henry J. Aaron, a Brookings Institution scholar, and Alicia Munnell, a former Clinton Administration economic adviser, pointed out in 1992 that the FETTs created substantial rewards for tax avoidance activities. They echoed Columbia law school professor George Cooper's description of the levies as "voluntary taxes." Out of $123 billion transferred across generations in 1986, a mere $36 billion was reported on estate tax returns, resulting in $6 billion in federal collections that year. "Informed observers," these experts noted, "think that decedents could have avoided even this modest toll if they had taken the time to do so."5 Tax avoidance requires the services of skilled estate planners. The federal estate transfer taxes nurture an industry that employs thousands of highly educated and highly remunerated professionals. In the early 1990s, the American Bar Association reported that approximately 16,000 (5 percent) of its members described their area of concentration as trust, probate, and estate law. This total does not include the number of accountants and financial planners who offer estate-planning services.6 Tax avoidance activity has several facets. All involve reducing the size of the estate by the time the property owner dies to avoid the death tax- basically a second tax on assets purchased with after-tax income. Common methods of tax avoidance include making direct transfers from the estate to such legal entities as trusts or limited partnerships, or as carefully planned gifts.7 Another is replacing monetary compensation for highly paid corporate executives with life insurance. Yet another is the use of experts to procure a low estimate of the value of the estate.8Heritage economist William Beach argues that the FETTs are a significant determinant of the cost of capital-the higher the level of such taxes, the higher the required rate of return on capital investments. The reason, he explains, is that "when individuals begin to see that their income and investment efforts will produce a future taxable estate, they…increase their earnings requirements to build the funds needed to pay the future wealth transfer taxes."9 This higher earnings requirement can be observed in the national economy as a higher user cost of capital than would otherwise prevail. The higher user cost of capital discourages investment and creates a bias among affected property owners in favor of consumption. MIT economist James M. Poterba estimates that federal estate transfer taxes add at least 1.3 percent to the cost of owning capital in the United States.10 Fullenbaum and McNeill describe estate transfer taxes as reductions in the after-tax wages of affected workers.11 Economic theory suggests that, all other things being equal, public policies that broadly reduce after-tax wages reduce labor force participation rates.12 According to Beach, this reduction reached 97,200 persons in 1996.13Eliminating the FETTs permanently and immediately would reverse these damaging effects on the national economy. Thousands of federal estate tax lawyers would be freed to engage in activities more closely associated with economic growth; the user cost of capital in the national economy would fall, making more types of investment immediately attractive and thus spurring investments overall; and a disincentive that keeps thousands of Americans out of the labor force would disappear.14
The Heritage Analysis of FETT Repeal
In addition to these behavioral aspects of tax policy changes, the CDA analysts considered the interaction between FETT repeal and capital gains tax collections, as well as between FETT repeal and federal spending.
Federal Spending. CDA analysts assumed that overall federal government spending would be adjusted according to changes in tax collections caused by eliminating the FETTs. This assumption assures that there would be virtually no change in the cumulative federal surplus during the 10-year period from fiscal years 2003-2012.19 Year-to-year variations in surpluses do occur. CDA analysts channeled these spending changes through adjustments in federal non-defense spending and federal grants-in-aid to state and local governments.
A Dynamic Analysis of Immediate FETT Repeal
Benefits of Eliminating Estate Transfer Taxes
Table 2 in the Appendix displays the difference in economic results between the policy of repeal and the current-law policy as reflected in the adapted DRI-WEFA model. The table shows that immediate and permanent FETT repeal would increase the nation's economic growth compared with what would happen under the currently planned temporary phaseout of such taxes. In the absence of further tax reform, immediate and permanent repeal would increase federal revenues over the following 10 years as well as:
Strengthen economic growth. By the end of FY 2012, GDP would be $14.7 billion higher (after adjusting for inflation) under FETT repeal than it would under current law (as projected by the CBO). Moreover, average GDP between 2003 and 2012 would run $10.6 billion higher.
Create more job opportunities. With the FETTs eliminated, the economy would support 118,000 more jobs by 2012 than it would under current law. Between 2003 and 2012, the average national employment level would run 104,000 jobs higher under repeal than it would otherwise.
Reduce unemployment. Immediate and permanent repeal of the FETTs also would reduce unemployment by 27,000 persons in 2012. The average number of unemployed for the 10 years following repeal would be 13,000 lower than without repeal.
Raise disposable personal income. Under elimination of the FETTs, personal disposable income would be $11.0 billion higher by the end of FY 2012, with immediate repeal, than it would without it. Average personal disposable income during 2003-2012 would be $10.3 billion higher under repeal.
Increase non-residential investment. Repeal of the estate tax would improve the investment environment enough to raise investment by $7.3 billion (adjusted for inflation) by 2012. Non-residential capital stock would be $25.1 billion higher. The user cost of capital would be 0.3 percent lower by 2012 than it would be if the FETTs were not eliminated.
Leave relative price levels and key interest rates unaffected. In spite of the stimulating effect FETT repeal would have on economic activity, it would not significantly affect either the consumer price index (CPI) or key government interest rates.
A slight decline in the federal publicly held debt during 2012. During the first years after repeal of the FETTs, the decline in federal revenue would raise the federal publicly held debt above where it would be under current law, reaching an inflation-adjusted $22.1 billion above the CBO's projection for 2007. This margin would then decline, reaching $5.7 billion below the CBO-projected level by 2012.
Conclusion
The tax cuts President Bush signed into law last year incorporate the phasing out and temporary abolition of the federal estate tax (FET) and generation-skipping taxes (GST). This move signaled Congress's willingness to consider key reforms of this tax.
However, the law allows the FET and other estate or wealth transfer taxes to return in 2011. These estate taxes have damaging economic effects, slowing economic growth and reducing potential increases in employment. A temporary phasing out of the federal estate transfer taxes will not address either of these detriments. As this CDA analysis shows, after just 10 years, an immediate and permanent repeal of the FET and other federal estate transfer taxes would strengthen economic activity, create hundreds of thousands of new jobs, bolster disposable income by $11 billion, reduce unemployment, and raise revenue while leaving the nation with a lower federal publicly held debt by FY 2011. -Alfredo B. Goyburu is a Policy Analyst in the Center for Data Analysis at The Heritage Foundation.APPENDIX
Methodology
Heritage Foundation economists in the Center for Data Analysis (CDA) followed a two-step procedure in identifying the 10-year economic and budgetary impact of an immediate and permanent repeal of the federal estate transfer taxes (FETTs) effective January 1, 2003.
First, CDA analysts applied Congressional Budget Office (CBO) projections for FETT collections under current law.25 As a working assumption, they used the negative of these collection estimates as a preliminary estimate of the federal revenue that would be lost under FETT repeal. To this estimate, CDA analysts applied a projection of the additional capital gains taxes that would be collected as a result of an FETT repeal, with a first $1 million exemption plus a $3 million spousal exemption, which produced a modified preliminary estimate for federal revenue loss. (See Table 1.)26
Using this modified preliminary estimate as an ultimate forecast of the federal revenue loss resulting from FETT repeal, however, would be to implement an erroneous static approach to an analysis of the effects of that tax policy change. The more correct (dynamic) approach is to take account of the macroeconomic effects of the tax policy change. These effects include changes in gross domestic product (GDP), interest rates, employment levels, personal income, and inflation. Any of these macroeconomic quantities could affect tax revenues significantly.
Second, CDA analysts introduced the modified preliminary estimate of tax revenue change into an especially adapted version of the DRI-WEFA U.S. Macroeconomic Model.27 They then processed the simulation and noted changes in key macroeconomic and budget variables compared with their values in the original adapted version of the model. Differences in these key variables were attributed to the response of the U.S. economy and federal budget to the tax policy change-that is, the dynamic response. (See Table 2.)
The Simulation28
The DRI-WEFA model contains a number of variables used to simulate policy changes. CDA analysts introduced static tax revenue and economic behavior change estimates to the model in order to find the dynamic responses of the U.S. economy and federal budget during 2003-2012 to immediate and permanent repeal of the FETTs. These include:
Civilian Labor Force. Heritage economist William W. Beach estimated in 1996 that the FETTs reduced the labor supply by 97,200 in 1996.29 CDA analysts revised this estimate to 103,900 using more recent information on the nation's civilian labor force growth rate from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. They adjusted the variable controlling labor supply in the model accordingly, phasing in the 103,900-worker increase over two years.
Non-NIPA30Federal Government Revenue. This variable measures taxes paid to the federal government not coming from income flows in the economy, such as the estate tax and the capital gains tax. CDA economists adjusted this variable according to the net static change in federal collections of these two types of tax resulting from the tax policy reform.
Business Sector Price Index. CDA analysts reduced this variable during the forecast period in order to reflect lowered compliance costs for the business sector resulting from FETT repeal. The adjustments corresponded to a reduction in business sector costs of 30 cents for every dollar that would have been collected in federal estate transfer taxes. This ratio is based on previous research cited by former DRI/McGraw-Hill economists Richard Fullenbaum and Mariana McNeill.31
Corporate AAA Bond Rate. MIT economist James M. Poterba estimated in a 2000 study that eliminating wealth transfer taxes would reduce the required yield on investment by at least 1.3 percent.[32] CDA analysts lowered the corporate AAA bond rate within the model in order to reflect this 1.3 percent reduction.
Federal Non-Defense Spending Variables. CDA economists adjusted federal spending in order to compensate for the projected changes in federal collections resulting from FETT repeal. This adjustment assured that the tax policy reform would not cause a substantial change in cumulative federal deficits during the forecast period. The adjusted variables controlled direct federal non-defense spending and federal grants-in-aid to state and local governments.
[2]All inflation-adjusted dollars referenced in this report are indexed to the 1996 overall price level and thus represent 1996 dollars.
[3]Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mariana A. McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," Research Institute for Small and Emerging Business, Working Paper Series No. 98-01, 1998, pp. 10-11.
[4]William W. Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1091, August 21, 1996, p. 26.
[5]Henry J. Aaron and Alicia Munnell, " Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," National Tax Journal, Vol. 45, No. 2 (June 1992), pp. 133-134, at .
[7]A number of financial counseling firms list transfers to trusts and carefully planned gifts on their Internet sites as key estate planning techniques. See, for example, Prudential Financial at http://www.prudential.com/productsAndServices/0,1474,intPageID%253D1350%2526blnPrinterFriendly%253D0,00.html; Dana S. Beane & Company, P.C., at http://www.dsbcpas.com/estatetaxplanning/estateplanningtech.html; and Deborah A. Malkin, Attorney at Law, at http://www.malkintrust.com/Avoid-Estate-Taxes.htm (October 25, 2002).
[8]Aaron and Munnell, "Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," pp. 135, 137.
[9]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.
[10]James M. Poterba, "Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns," in Joel M. Slemrod, ed., Does Atlas Shrug? (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2000), p. 339. Beach estimates that the FETTs add 3 percent to the cost of owning capital. See Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.
[11]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 10.
[12]All other things held constant, economic theory suggests unambiguously that reductions in after-tax wages reduce the number of participants in the labor force, since both the wealth and the substitution effect reinforce one another, rather than offset one another, in this case.
[13]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.
[15]Estimated by extrapolating unpublished projections for estate tax filings by fiscal year performed by the Statistics of Income Program of the Internal Revenue Service.
[16]Projections for estate tax filings through 2010 from unpublished Statistics of Income Program projections.
[17]Joint Committee on Taxation, "Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2002-2006," January 17, 2002, p. 23, at http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=2002_joint_committee_on_taxation&docid=f:76452.pdf.
[18]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 9.
[20]The Center for Data Analysis used the Mark 11 U.S. Macroeconomic Model of DRI-WEFA, Inc. (now known as Global Insight), to conduct this analysis. The model was developed in the late 1960s by Nobel Prize-winning economist Lawrence Klein and several colleagues at the University of Pennsylvania. It is widely used by Fortune 500 companies, prominent federal agencies, and economic forecasting departments. The methodologies, assumptions, conclusions, and opinions herein are entirely the work of Heritage Foundation analysts. They have not been endorsed by, nor do they necessarily reflect the views of, the owners of the model.
[21]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," August 2002, at http://www.cbo.gov/showdoc.cfm?index=3735&sequence=0.
[22]For a discussion of the shortcomings of static analysis of the effects of tax policy changes, see Daniel J. Mitchell, "The Correct Way to Measure the Revenue Impact of Changes in Tax Rates," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1544, May 3, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/BG1544.cfm; see also "The Argument for Reality-Based Scoring," Heritage Foundation Web Memo No. 92, March 29, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/WM92.cfm, and Daniel R. Burton, "Reforming the Federal Tax Policy Process," Cato Policy Analysis, forthcoming December 2002.
[23]The variables changed in this simulation for the purpose of modeling FETT repeal are enumerated in the Appendix.
[24]Table 2 shows year-by-year estimates of how repeal of the FETTs would likely change major economic indicators.
[25]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," p. 48.
[26]CDA economists applied a staged process to calculate the additional capital gains tax collections. The first stage was to combine historical averages on federal estate tax returns from the IRS Statistics of Income Program and modified projections from the Joint Committee on Taxation on the current-law capital gains tax exclusion at death. These together yielded a projection of the amount of taxable capital gains held in estates over and above the $1 million exemption, without taking into account the higher spousal exemption. The second stage was for CDA analysts to use historical averages to find how much the higher $3 million spousal exemption would subtract from the first projection of taxable capital gains. The final stage involved applying the long-term capital gains tax rate to the modified projection for non-exempt taxable capital gains to create a projection of the additional capital gains tax collections under FETT repeal.
[27]This version of the model is especially adapted to embody economic and budgetary projections published by the CBO in August 2002.
[28]Readers interested in replicating this analysis should contact the author for further information on how the model was applied.
[29]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 26.
[30]NIPA stands for National Income and Product Accounts.
[31]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," pp. A1 and A2. These two authors cited four sources for this estimate. The first estimate, by Guest and Associates, L.L.C., was based upon survey data to find the amount that estate holders spent on federal estate tax planning and preparation during 1995; this amount was compared with 1995 FETT collections and yielded a ratio of 30 percent. The second estimate was based upon calculations for FETT compliance costs by Kennesaw State University scholars Joseph Astrachan and Craig Aranoff; the cost was divided by an annual FETT collection total, resulting in a ratio of 32 percent. The third estimate was from Christopher E. Erblich of the Tax and Estate Planning Practice Group, who calculated both compliance and economic disincentive costs resulting from the U.S. federal tax system; Erblich's amount was divided by an annual total for FETT collection, yielding a ratio close to 31.2 percent. Finally, CDA economist William W. Beach provided an estimate of the 1995 cost of compliance with FETT that, when compared to 1995 FETT collections, resulted in a ratio of 29.8 percent.
APPENDIX
Methodology
Heritage Foundation economists in the Center for Data Analysis (CDA) followed a two-step procedure in identifying the 10-year economic and budgetary impact of an immediate and permanent repeal of the federal estate transfer taxes (FETTs) effective January 1, 2003.
First, CDA analysts applied Congressional Budget Office (CBO) projections for FETT collections under current law.25 As a working assumption, they used the negative of these collection estimates as a preliminary estimate of the federal revenue that would be lost under FETT repeal. To this estimate, CDA analysts applied a projection of the additional capital gains taxes that would be collected as a result of an FETT repeal, with a first $1 million exemption plus a $3 million spousal exemption, which produced a modified preliminary estimate for federal revenue loss. (See Table 1.)26
Using this modified preliminary estimate as an ultimate forecast of the federal revenue loss resulting from FETT repeal, however, would be to implement an erroneous static approach to an analysis of the effects of that tax policy change. The more correct (dynamic) approach is to take account of the macroeconomic effects of the tax policy change. These effects include changes in gross domestic product (GDP), interest rates, employment levels, personal income, and inflation. Any of these macroeconomic quantities could affect tax revenues significantly.
Second, CDA analysts introduced the modified preliminary estimate of tax revenue change into an especially adapted version of the DRI-WEFA U.S. Macroeconomic Model.27 They then processed the simulation and noted changes in key macroeconomic and budget variables compared with their values in the original adapted version of the model. Differences in these key variables were attributed to the response of the U.S. economy and federal budget to the tax policy change-that is, the dynamic response. (See Table 2.)
The Simulation28
The DRI-WEFA model contains a number of variables used to simulate policy changes. CDA analysts introduced static tax revenue and economic behavior change estimates to the model in order to find the dynamic responses of the U.S. economy and federal budget during 2003-2012 to immediate and permanent repeal of the FETTs. These include:
Civilian Labor Force. Heritage economist William W. Beach estimated in 1996 that the FETTs reduced the labor supply by 97,200 in 1996.29 CDA analysts revised this estimate to 103,900 using more recent information on the nation's civilian labor force growth rate from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. They adjusted the variable controlling labor supply in the model accordingly, phasing in the 103,900-worker increase over two years.
Non-NIPA30Federal Government Revenue. This variable measures taxes paid to the federal government not coming from income flows in the economy, such as the estate tax and the capital gains tax. CDA economists adjusted this variable according to the net static change in federal collections of these two types of tax resulting from the tax policy reform.
Business Sector Price Index. CDA analysts reduced this variable during the forecast period in order to reflect lowered compliance costs for the business sector resulting from FETT repeal. The adjustments corresponded to a reduction in business sector costs of 30 cents for every dollar that would have been collected in federal estate transfer taxes. This ratio is based on previous research cited by former DRI/McGraw-Hill economists Richard Fullenbaum and Mariana McNeill.31
Corporate AAA Bond Rate. MIT economist James M. Poterba estimated in a 2000 study that eliminating wealth transfer taxes would reduce the required yield on investment by at least 1.3 percent.[32] CDA analysts lowered the corporate AAA bond rate within the model in order to reflect this 1.3 percent reduction.
Federal Non-Defense Spending Variables. CDA economists adjusted federal spending in order to compensate for the projected changes in federal collections resulting from FETT repeal. This adjustment assured that the tax policy reform would not cause a substantial change in cumulative federal deficits during the forecast period. The adjusted variables controlled direct federal non-defense spending and federal grants-in-aid to state and local governments.
[2]All inflation-adjusted dollars referenced in this report are indexed to the 1996 overall price level and thus represent 1996 dollars.
[3]Richard F. Fullenbaum and Mariana A. McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," Research Institute for Small and Emerging Business, Working Paper Series No. 98-01, 1998, pp. 10-11.
[4]William W. Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1091, August 21, 1996, p. 26.
[5]Henry J. Aaron and Alicia Munnell, " Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," National Tax Journal, Vol. 45, No. 2 (June 1992), pp. 133-134, at .
[7]A number of financial counseling firms list transfers to trusts and carefully planned gifts on their Internet sites as key estate planning techniques. See, for example, Prudential Financial at http://www.prudential.com/productsAndServices/0,1474,intPageID%253D1350%2526blnPrinterFriendly%253D0,00.html; Dana S. Beane & Company, P.C., at http://www.dsbcpas.com/estatetaxplanning/estateplanningtech.html; and Deborah A. Malkin, Attorney at Law, at http://www.malkintrust.com/Avoid-Estate-Taxes.htm (October 25, 2002).
[8]Aaron and Munnell, "Reassessing the Role for Wealth Transfer Taxes," pp. 135, 137.
[9]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.
[10]James M. Poterba, "Estate Tax and After-Tax Investment Returns," in Joel M. Slemrod, ed., Does Atlas Shrug? (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 2000), p. 339. Beach estimates that the FETTs add 3 percent to the cost of owning capital. See Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.
[11]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 10.
[12]All other things held constant, economic theory suggests unambiguously that reductions in after-tax wages reduce the number of participants in the labor force, since both the wealth and the substitution effect reinforce one another, rather than offset one another, in this case.
[13]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 24.
[15]Estimated by extrapolating unpublished projections for estate tax filings by fiscal year performed by the Statistics of Income Program of the Internal Revenue Service.
[16]Projections for estate tax filings through 2010 from unpublished Statistics of Income Program projections.
[17]Joint Committee on Taxation, "Estimates of Federal Tax Expenditures for Fiscal Years 2002-2006," January 17, 2002, p. 23, at http://frwebgate.access.gpo.gov/cgi-bin/getdoc.cgi?dbname=2002_joint_committee_on_taxation&docid=f:76452.pdf.
[18]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," p. 9.
[20]The Center for Data Analysis used the Mark 11 U.S. Macroeconomic Model of DRI-WEFA, Inc. (now known as Global Insight), to conduct this analysis. The model was developed in the late 1960s by Nobel Prize-winning economist Lawrence Klein and several colleagues at the University of Pennsylvania. It is widely used by Fortune 500 companies, prominent federal agencies, and economic forecasting departments. The methodologies, assumptions, conclusions, and opinions herein are entirely the work of Heritage Foundation analysts. They have not been endorsed by, nor do they necessarily reflect the views of, the owners of the model.
[21]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," August 2002, at http://www.cbo.gov/showdoc.cfm?index=3735&sequence=0.
[22]For a discussion of the shortcomings of static analysis of the effects of tax policy changes, see Daniel J. Mitchell, "The Correct Way to Measure the Revenue Impact of Changes in Tax Rates," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 1544, May 3, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/BG1544.cfm; see also "The Argument for Reality-Based Scoring," Heritage Foundation Web Memo No. 92, March 29, 2002, at http://www.heritage.org/Research/Taxes/WM92.cfm, and Daniel R. Burton, "Reforming the Federal Tax Policy Process," Cato Policy Analysis, forthcoming December 2002.
[23]The variables changed in this simulation for the purpose of modeling FETT repeal are enumerated in the Appendix.
[24]Table 2 shows year-by-year estimates of how repeal of the FETTs would likely change major economic indicators.
[25]Congressional Budget Office, "The Budget and Economic Outlook: An Update," p. 48.
[26]CDA economists applied a staged process to calculate the additional capital gains tax collections. The first stage was to combine historical averages on federal estate tax returns from the IRS Statistics of Income Program and modified projections from the Joint Committee on Taxation on the current-law capital gains tax exclusion at death. These together yielded a projection of the amount of taxable capital gains held in estates over and above the $1 million exemption, without taking into account the higher spousal exemption. The second stage was for CDA analysts to use historical averages to find how much the higher $3 million spousal exemption would subtract from the first projection of taxable capital gains. The final stage involved applying the long-term capital gains tax rate to the modified projection for non-exempt taxable capital gains to create a projection of the additional capital gains tax collections under FETT repeal.
[27]This version of the model is especially adapted to embody economic and budgetary projections published by the CBO in August 2002.
[28]Readers interested in replicating this analysis should contact the author for further information on how the model was applied.
[29]Beach, "The Case for Repealing the Estate Tax," p. 26.
[30]NIPA stands for National Income and Product Accounts.
[31]Fullenbaum and McNeill, "The Effects of the Federal Estate and Gift Tax on the Aggregate Economy," pp. A1 and A2. These two authors cited four sources for this estimate. The first estimate, by Guest and Associates, L.L.C., was based upon survey data to find the amount that estate holders spent on federal estate tax planning and preparation during 1995; this amount was compared with 1995 FETT collections and yielded a ratio of 30 percent. The second estimate was based upon calculations for FETT compliance costs by Kennesaw State University scholars Joseph Astrachan and Craig Aranoff; the cost was divided by an annual FETT collection total, resulting in a ratio of 32 percent. The third estimate was from Christopher E. Erblich of the Tax and Estate Planning Practice Group, who calculated both compliance and economic disincentive costs resulting from the U.S. federal tax system; Erblich's amount was divided by an annual total for FETT collection, yielding a ratio close to 31.2 percent. Finally, CDA economist William W. Beach provided an estimate of the 1995 cost of compliance with FETT that, when compared to 1995 FETT collections, resulted in a ratio of 29.8 percent.