[{"command":"add_css","data":[{"rel":"stylesheet","media":"all","href":"\/sites\/default\/files\/css\/css_rZjCmUBEHftE91DeNru5KqLSSaOmvYzpnCjBdzKdLqM.css?delta=0\u0026language=en\u0026theme=heritage_theme\u0026include=eJwrTi1LzdNPzkksLq7Uy8tPSQUAPMsGtA"}]},{"command":"invoke","selector":null,"method":"openEssay","args":["10000033","\n\n\u003Carticle about=\u0022\/constitution\/articles\/1\/essays\/34\/spending-clause\u0022 class=\u0022node node--type-constitution-essay node--promoted node--view-mode-embedded clearfix\u0022\u003E\n \u003Ch1 class=\u0022title\u0022\u003E\u003Cspan\u003ESpending Clause\u003C\/span\u003E\n\u003C\/h1\u003E\n\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-location\u0022\u003E\n Article I, Section 8, Clause 1\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-context\u0022\u003E\n \n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp\u003EThe Congress shall have Power To lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises, to pay the Debts and provide for the common Defence and general Welfare of the United States....\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-body\u0022\u003E\n \n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp\u003EAlthough, taken as whole, Article I, Section 8,\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003EClause 1 is the source of congressional authority to levy taxes (\u003Ci\u003Esee\u003C\/i\u003E Taxation Clause), it permits the levying of taxes for two purposes only: to pay the debts of the United States, and to provide for the \u201ccommon Defence and general Welfare\u201d of the United States. Taken together, these purposes have traditionally been held to imply and constitute the \u201cSpending Power.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EAs a matter of original meaning, there is reason to doubt whether the federal spending power flows from this clause. On its face, the clause grants only the power to tax, and any inference of a spending power from the clause\u2019s language about the \u201cgeneral Welfare\u201d leaves unexplained where Congress obtains the power to spend borrowed money or the proceeds from land sales. It is more plausible to locate the federal spending power in the Necessary and Proper Clause, or perhaps even the Territories and Property Clauses of Article IV. Nonetheless, modern law has settled on the Taxation Clause as the source of federal spending authority, though a more accurate description would be to entitle the clause as \u201cThe General Welfare Clause.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EEven so, many legal scholars and jurists today believe that the two purposes of the Spending Clause (to pay the debts of the United States and to provide for the common defense and \u201cgeneral Welfare\u201d of the United State) are so broad as to amount to no limitation at all. The contemporary view is that Congress\u2019s power to provide for the \u201cgeneral Welfare\u201d is a power to spend for virtually anything that Congress itself views as helpful. To be sure, some of the Founders, most notably Alexander Hamilton, supported an expansive spending power during the Constitutional Convention; but such proposals, including an explicit attempt to authorize spending by the federal government for internal improvements, were rejected by the Convention. Hamilton continued to press his case by arguing during George Washington\u2019s administration for an expansive interpretation of the clause (which Washington adopted). In his \u201cReport on Manufactures\u201d (1791), Hamilton contended that the only limits on the tax-and-spend power were the requirements that duties be uniform, that direct taxes be apportioned by population, and that no tax should be laid on articles exported from any state. The power to raise money was otherwise \u201cplenary, and indefinite,\u201d he argued, \u201cand the objects to which it may be appropriated are no less comprehensive.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EHamilton\u2019s broad reading met with opposition from many of the other Founders. James Madison repeatedly argued that the power to tax and spend did not confer upon Congress the right to do whatever it thought to be in the best interest of the nation, but only to further the ends specifically enumerated elsewhere in the Constitution, a position supported by Thomas Jefferson.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EThere was also a third interpretation, recognized later even by Alexander Hamilton. According to this intermediate view, the \u201ccommon Defence and general Welfare\u201d language is not, as Madison contended, a shorthand way of limiting the power to tax and spend in furtherance of the powers elsewhere enumerated in Article I, Section 8; but it does contain its own limitation, namely, that spending under the clause be for the \u201cgeneral\u201d (that is, national) welfare and not for purely local or regional benefit. President James Monroe later adopted this position\u2014albeit with more teeth than Hamilton had been willing to give it\u2014in his 1822 message vetoing a bill to preserve and repair the Cumberland Road. Monroe contended that Congress\u2019s power to spend was restricted \u201cto purposes of common defence, and of general, national, not local, or state, benefit.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EThere are relatively few examples from the early Congresses of debate over the scope of the spending power, but the few that do exist are enlightening. The First Congress refused to make a loan to a glass manufacturer after several Members expressed the view that such an appropriation would be unconstitutional, and the Fourth Congress did not believe it had the power to provide relief to the citizens of Savannah, Georgia, after a devastating fire destroyed the entire city. The debates do not reflect whether Congress thought such appropriations unconstitutional because they did not further other enumerated powers (Madison\u2019s position) or because they were of local rather than national benefit (Monroe\u2019s position), but they reflect a rejection of the broad interpretation of the spending power originally proffered by Hamilton.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EOn the other hand, Congress approved some appropriations for apparently local projects, but it can be argued that those projects were of general benefit or specifically tied to other enumerated powers, and hence within the authority conferred by Article I, Section 8. At the same time it was denying a request to fund the dredging of the Savannah River, for example, Congress approved an appropriation for a lighthouse at the entrance of the Chesapeake Bay. Both measures were important for navigation, but the lighthouse was of benefit to the coastal trade of the entire nation (and hence to interstate commerce), while the dredging operation was primarily of local, intrastate benefit to the people of Georgia and hence fell on the \u201clocal\u201d rather than the \u201cgeneral\u201d side of the public welfare line.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003ECongress approved various appropriations to fund a road across the Cumberland Gap, but it rejected as unconstitutional a larger appropriation for internal improvements of which the Cumberland Gap road project was a part. Congress accepted the view that it had no power under the Constitution to open roads and canals in any state; its power to fund the Cumberland Road was the result of the compact with Ohio \u201cfor which the nation receive[d] an equivalent,\u201d namely, Ohio\u2019s promise not to tax for five years any lands sold by the federal government in Ohio. Moreover, as George Washington had repeatedly urged while President, the opening of a road across the Cumberland Gap was strategically necessary to keep the western territories allied with the coastal states (rather than with the foreign powers that controlled the Mississippi river region at the time), something critically important to the security of the entire nation and not just the people of Ohio. The Cumberland Gap road was an example of a local project that directly benefited the nation. Appropriations for other local projects such as public education and local roads and canals, the \u201cgeneral\u201d benefit of which was less direct, were viewed as unconstitutional, and a proposal in Jefferson\u2019s 1806 State of the Union Address to amend the Constitution to permit funding for such internal improvements was never adopted.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EIn sum, although Alexander Hamilton and other leaders of the Federalist Party argued for an expansive reading of the spending power, their reading was, on the whole, rejected both by Congress and, after the election of 1800, by the executive. Indeed, the differing views on the scope of federal power was a principal ground upon which the 1800 presidential election contest between Jefferson and incumbent Federalist President John Adams was waged. As Jefferson would note in an 1817 letter to Albert Gallatin, the different interpretations of the Spending Clause put forward by Hamilton on the one hand, and Madison and Jefferson on the other were \u201calmost the only landmark which now divides the federalists from the republicans.\u201d Jefferson won that election, and, save for a brief interlude during the one-term presidency of John Quincy Adams, every President adopted the more restrictive interpretation of spending power until the Civil War.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EPresident Madison vetoed as unconstitutional an internal improvements bill that Congress passed at the very end of his presidency. President Monroe also rejected the expansive Hamiltonian view of the Spending Clause (albeit on slightly different grounds than Madison had), vetoing various attempts at internal improvement bills during most of his two terms. But in the last year of his presidency, finding the line between \u201cgeneral\u201d welfare and local welfare a hard one to define, Monroe signed a few bills to fund surveys for some local internal improvement projects. He thus opened a gate through which flowed a flood of spending on local projects during the administration of President John Quincy Adams.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EAdams\u2019s resurrection of the Hamiltonian position became the focus of the next presidential election, contributing to Adams\u2019s defeat at the hands of Andrew Jackson, who promptly put to rest \u201cthis dangerous doctrine\u201d by vetoing a $200 million appropriation for the purchase of stock in the Maysville and Lexington Turnpike Company and for the direct construction of other \u201cordinary\u201d roads and canals by the government itself. So strong was his veto message that for four years Congress did not even try to pass another such bill, and when in 1834 it passed an act to improve the navigation of the Wabash River, Jackson again responded forcefully, rejecting as a \u201cfallacy\u201d the contention that the Spending Clause conferred upon Congress the power to do whatever seemed \u201cto conduce to the public good.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EIn 1847 and 1857, Presidents James K. Polk and James Buchanan, respectively, vetoed subsequent congressional efforts to fund internal improvements. Polk vetoed a bill strikingly similar to much of the pork-barrel legislation to which we have grown accustomed in modern times. It provided $6,000 for projects in the Wisconsin territory\u2014constitutionally permissible because of Congress\u2019s broader powers over federal territories\u2014but it also included $500,000 for myriad projects in the existing states. Polk contended that to interpret the Spending Clause to permit such appropriations would allow \u201ccombinations of individual and local interests [that would be] strong enough to control legislation, absorb the revenues of the country, and plunge the government into a hopeless indebtedness.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003ESimilarly, in his message vetoing the college land grant bill, President Buchanan took it as a given that the funds raised by Congress from taxation were \u201cconfined to the execution of the enumerated powers delegated to Congress.\u201d The idea that the resources of the federal government\u2014either taxes or the public lands\u2014could be diverted to carry into effect any measure of state domestic policy that Congress saw fit to support \u201cwould be to confer upon Congress a vast and irresponsible authority, utterly at war with the well-known jealousy of Federal power which prevailed at the formation of the Constitution.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EThus, while there were clearly voices urging for an expansive spending power before the Civil War, the interpretation held by Jefferson, Madison, and Monroe is the one that prevailed for most of the first seventy years after adoption of the Constitution.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EModern-day jurisprudence on the Spending Clause begins with the New Deal-era case of \u003Ci\u003EUnited States v. Butler \u003C\/i\u003E(1936). In that case, both\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003Eparties relied upon the Hamiltonian position, despite the history recounted above. Both the majority and dissenting opinions of the Court facially accepted the correctness of Hamilton\u2019s position even though the majority ruled that the particular tax and regulatory program at issue in the case was unconstitutional because its purpose was to regulate and control agricultural production, \u201ca matter beyond the powers delegated to the federal government\u201d\u2014a holding much more in line with Madison\u2019s interpretation of the spending power than Hamilton\u2019s.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EMoreover, the Hamiltonian position purportedly adopted by the Court was not the expansive view that Congress could do whatever it deemed to be in the public interest, but the much more limited view that the limits on spending were contained in the Spending Clause itself and not in the remainder of Article I, Section 8. \u201cWhile, therefore, the power to tax is not unlimited,\u201d Justice Owen J. Roberts wrote, \u201cits confines are set in the clause which confers it, and not in those of Section 8 which bestow and define the legislative powers of the Congress.\u201d In other words, the only limitation on Congress\u2019s power to tax and spend was that the spending be for the \u201cgeneral Welfare\u201d\u2014the position actually advocated by James Monroe. What really makes \u003Ci\u003EButler \u003C\/i\u003Ea departure from the early interpretation\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003Eof the clause, then, was that it gave Congress virtually unlimited discretion to determine what was in the \u201cgeneral Welfare\u201d\u2014a holding that, practically speaking, is much more in line with the expansive Hamiltonian position than with the positions advocated either by Monroe or by Madison and Jefferson.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003ESince \u003Ci\u003EButler\u003C\/i\u003E and until \u003Ci\u003ENFIB v. Sebelius\u003C\/i\u003E (2012) the courts have treated whatever limitation the clause might impose as essentially a nonjusticiable political question. In the case of \u003Ci\u003ESouth\u003C\/i\u003E \u003Ci\u003EDakota v. Dole \u003C\/i\u003E(1987), for example, the Supreme\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003ECourt noted that \u201cthe level of deference to the congressional decision is such that the Court has more recently questioned whether \u2018general welfare\u2019 is a judicially enforceable restriction at all.\u201d Instead, the courts have focused not on the constitutionality of spending programs themselves, but on whether various conditions imposed on the receipt of federal funds\u2014conditions designed to achieve ends concededly not within Congress\u2019s enumerated powers\u2014were constitutionally permissible.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EIn \u003Ci\u003ESouth Dakota v. Dole\u003C\/i\u003E, the State of South Dakota challenged the constitutionality of a federal statute conditioning states\u2019 receipt of a portion of federal highway funds on the state\u2019s raising its minimum drinking age to twenty-one. \u003Ci\u003EDole \u003C\/i\u003Eupheld the federal spending restriction and\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003Ethe Court adopted a four-prong test to assess the constitutionality of spending conditions: (1) the spending power must be in pursuit of the \u201cgeneral Welfare,\u201d a requirement that the Court left to Congress\u2019s judgment to satisfy because, in its view, \u201cthe concept of welfare or the opposite is shaped by Congress\u201d; (2) whether the conditions imposed were unambiguous (so the states know what they are agreeing to); (3) whether they were related to the particular national projects or programs being funded (thus far, the Court has not invalidated a spending restriction on the grounds that it is too unrelated to the programs being funded); and (4) whether there are other constitutional provisions that provide an independent bar to the conditional grant of federal funds. For example, Congress could not impose as a condition that a state receiving federal funds for its welfare programs require welfare recipients to waive their Fourth Amendment rights.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003E\u003Ci\u003EDole \u003C\/i\u003Ealso added another test: \u201cOur decisions have recognized that in some circumstances the financial inducement offered by Congress might be so coercive as to pass the point at which \u2018pressure turns into compulsion.\u2019\u201d The Court then briefly announced that there was no coercion because states that refused to raise their drinking age to twenty-one would \u201close a relatively small percentage of certain federal highway funds.\u201d\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EOf these requirements, only the requirement that the condition be unambiguous has received much play in the courts. Yet that requirement is more an issue of legislative drafting than of actual limits on Congress\u2019s spending power. The Court has thus far been highly deferential to Congress in its assessment of the other requirements, which at least offer some prospect of limiting Congress\u2019s spending power should the Court decide to put some teeth into them. Yet the facts of \u003Ci\u003ESouth\u003C\/i\u003E \u003Ci\u003EDakota v. Dole \u003C\/i\u003Eitself demonstrate just how little teeth those requirements have. The Court concluded in that case that conditioning receipt of federal highway funds on a state\u2019s adoption of a drinking age of twenty-one was sufficiently related to the funding program. Eighteen-year-old residents of states that had a drinking age of twenty-one would drive to border states where the drinking age was eighteen to procure their liquor, the argument went. When driving back, the drivers had an increased risk of drunk driving on the highways paved by federal funds, and that was a sufficient connection for the Court.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EBoth Justices William J. Brennan, Jr., and Sandra Day O\u2019Connor dissented. Justice O\u2019Connor noted in her \u003Ci\u003ESouth Dakota v. Dole\u003C\/i\u003E dissent: \u201cIf the spending power is to be limited only by Congress\u2019 notion of the general welfare, the reality\u2009.\u2009.\u2009.\u2009is that the Spending Clause gives \u2018power to the Congress\u2009.\u2009.\u2009.\u2009to become a parliament of the whole people, subject to no restrictions save such as are self-imposed.\u2019 This\u2009.\u2009.\u2009.\u2009was not the Framers\u2019 plan and it is not the meaning of the Spending Clause.\u201d The Supreme Court had also been suggesting since its decision in \u003Ci\u003EButler\u003C\/i\u003E that the spending power could not be used to \u201ccoerce\u201d action that, because of constitutional principles of federalism, were properly left to the States. But in the 75 years following \u003Ci\u003EButler\u003C\/i\u003E, the Court never held that a congressional spending program violated the coercion principle until its decision in the 2012 health care case, \u003Ci\u003ENFIB\u003C\/i\u003E \u003Ci\u003Ev. Sebelius\u003C\/i\u003E. In that case, the Court held (by a vote of 7\u20132) that Congress\u2019s threat to withhold \u003Ci\u003Eall\u003C\/i\u003E existing Medicaid program funds from states that chose not to participate in the significant expansion of that program mandated by the 2010 Affordable Care Act was unduly coercive, a \u201cgun to the head\u201d of the states, and \u201ceconomic dragooning\u201d that left \u201cthe States with no real option but to acquiesce in the Medicaid expansion.\u201d But the Court then severed that penalty from the rest of the statute, leaving the expanded Medicaid spending program in place. As a result, the other coercion problem inherent in the Act was permitted to stand, and states were still left with an unpalatable choice: either participate in the expansion demanded by Congress or decline to participate and watch billions of dollars in tax revenues flow from the state\u2019s own citizens to fund Medicaid programs in other states. And the Court did not even consider that such massive transfers of tax revenues from non-participating to participating states might not qualify as spending in the \u201cgeneral\u201d welfare.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp\u003EThus, while the Court has recently restored some limits to other powers delegated to Congress (such as the Commerce Clause), the spending power remains virtually unlimited in contemporary jurisprudence, contrary to the evident views of most of the Constitution\u2019s Framers. This does not prevent Congress from adopting on its own a view of its power to spend that is more in accord with those of the Founders, of course, but the spending power appears to be one whose limits the Court will not enforce.\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \n \u003C\/div\u003E\n\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-author\u0022\u003E\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-author--media\u0022\u003E\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-author--photo\u0022 style=\u0022background-image: url(\/sites\/default\/files\/John_Eastman.jpg)\u0022\u003E\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-author--info\u0022\u003E\n \u003Ch4 class=\u0022con-essay-author--name\u0022\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022http:\/\/www.chapman.edu\/law\/faculty\/eastman.asp\u0022\u003EJohn C. Eastman\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003C\/h4\u003E\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-author--job\u0022\u003E\n Henry Salvatori Professor of Law \u0026amp; Community Service, Chapman University School of Law\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n\n \u003Cdiv class=\u0022con-essay-tabs\u0022\u003E\n \u003Cul data-tabs class=\u0022tabs\u0022\u003E\n \u003Cli class=\u0022button-more thirds\u0022\u003E\u003Ca data-tab href=\u0022#node-10000033-taba\u0022\u003EFurther Reading\u003C\/a\u003E\u003C\/li\u003E\n \u003Cli class=\u0022button-more thirds\u0022\u003E\u003Ca data-tab href=\u0022#node-10000033-tabb\u0022\u003ECase Law\u003C\/a\u003E\u003C\/li\u003E\n \u003Cli class=\u0022button-more thirds\u0022\u003E\u003Ca data-tab href=\u0022#node-10000033-tabc\u0022\u003ERelated Essays\u003C\/a\u003E\u003C\/li\u003E\n \u003C\/ul\u003E\n\n \u003Cdiv data-tabs-content\u003E\n \u003Cdiv data-tabs-pane class=\u0022tabs-pane\u0022 id=\u0022node-10000033-taba\u0022\u003E\n \n \u003Cdiv\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003ELynn A. Baker, \u003Ci\u003EConditional Federal Spending After\u003C\/i\u003E \u003Ci\u003ELopez\u003C\/i\u003E, 95\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003ECOLUM. L. REV. 1911 (1995)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp\u003EErwin Chemerinsky, \u003Ci\u003EProtecting the Spending Power\u003C\/i\u003E, 4\u003C\/p\u003E\n\n\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px\u0022\u003ECHAP. L. REV. 89 (2001)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003EJohn C. Eastman, \u003Ci\u003ERestoring the \u201cGeneral\u201d to the General Welfare Clause\u003C\/i\u003E, 4\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003ECHAP. L. REV. 63 (2001)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003EDavid E. Engdahl, \u003Ci\u003EThe Spending Power\u003C\/i\u003E, 44 DUKE L.J. 1 (1994)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003EGARY LAWSON \u0026amp; GUY SEIDMAN, THE CONSTITUTION OF EMPIRE: TERRITORIAL EXPANSION AND AMERICAN LEGAL HISTORY 23\u201332 (2004)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003ECelestine Richards McConville\u003Ci\u003E, Federal Funding\u003C\/i\u003E \u003Ci\u003EConditions: Bursting Through the Dole Loopholes\u003C\/i\u003E,\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003E4 CHAP. L. REV. 163 (2001)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003ERobert G. Natelson, \u003Ci\u003EThe General Welfare Clause and\u003C\/i\u003E \u003Ci\u003Ethe Public Trust: An Essay in Original Understanding\u003C\/i\u003E, 52\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003EU. KAN. L. REV. 1 (2003)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-align:justify; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003EJeffrey T. Renz, \u003Ci\u003EWhat Spending Clause? (Or the President\u2019s Paramour): An Examination of the Views of Hamilton, Madison, and Story on Article I, Section 8, Clause 1 of the United States Constitution\u003C\/i\u003E, 33\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003EJ.\u003Ci\u003E \u003C\/i\u003EMARSHALL L. REV. 81 (1999)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv data-tabs-pane class=\u0022tabs-pane\u0022 id=\u0022node-10000033-tabb\u0022\u003E\n \n \u003Cdiv\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp\u003EUnited States v. Butler, 297 U.S. 1 (1936)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp\u003ESouth Dakota v. Dole, 483 U.S. 203 (1987)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv\u003E\u003Cp style=\u0022margin-left:16px; text-indent:-11.95pt\u0022\u003ENational Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius, 132 S. Ct. 2566 (2012)\u003C\/p\u003E\n\u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003Cdiv data-tabs-pane class=\u0022tabs-pane\u0022 id=\u0022node-10000033-tabc\u0022\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/17848985\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003ETaxation\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000034\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003EUniformity Clause\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000037\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003ECommerce Among the States\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000056\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003EEnclave Clause\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000058\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003ENecessary and Proper Clause\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000063\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003EDirect Taxes\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000064\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003EExport Taxation Clause\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003Ca href=\u0022\/essay_controller\/10000125\u0022 class=\u0022use-ajax\u0022\u003EProperty Clause\u003C\/a\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \u003C\/div\u003E\n \n\u003C\/article\u003E\n"]}]