Introduction
As Congress begins work on a reconciliation bill to put into
place legislation to flesh out the entitlement spending targets of
the recent budget agreement, lawmakers are considering ways to
reform Medicare. These reforms not only must achieve the short-term
budget targets, but also must begin the task of achieving
structural reforms that will bring about long-term savings through
efficiency while modernizing and improving the program.
An increasing number of lawmakers, among them Senators John Breaux
(D-LA), Connie Mack (R-FL), and Ron Wyden (D-OR), have shown an
interest in reforming Medicare by introducing key features of the
health care system that covers Members of Congress and over 9
million other federal employees and retirees. This program-the
Federal Employees Health Benefits Program (FEHBP)-has been
attracting a great deal of attention recently, including a day of
hearings before the Senate Finance Committee. Using the FEHBP as
the foundation for Medicare reform would be compatible with the
outline of reform now being prepared by the leadership in both
houses of Congress.
This growing interest is hardly surprising. The FEHBP and Medicare
both are large programs run by the federal government, but the
similarity ends there. The FEHBP is not experiencing the severe
financial problems faced by Medicare. It is run by a very small
bureaucracy that, unlike Medicare's, does not try to set prices for
doctors and hospitals. It offers choices of modern benefits and
private plans to federal retirees (and active workers) that are
unavailable in Medicare. It provides comprehensive information to
enrollees. And it uses a completely different payment system that
blends a formula with negotiations to achieve a remarkable level of
cost control while constantly improving benefits and enjoying wide
popularity.
The FEHBP experience should convince Congress that, with some
modification of the basic FEHBP design, it is possible to design a
stable choice system for people on Medicare that would provide
constantly upgraded benefits to retirees. As former Congressional
Budget Office (CBO) Director Robert Reischauer recently testified,
the "FEHBP shows that it is possible to create a smoothly
functioning market system of national scope in which a number of
different types of plans compete for enrollment." Reischauer added
that the "FEHBP's experience also suggests that an effective
competitive market can function without a sophisticated mechanism
for risk adjusting payments to plans."1
If Congress is to improve Medicare by incorporating features of
the FEHBP, however, it is crucial that Members understand the
FEHBP's key ingredients, how it really works, and precisely which
of its features should be incorporated, not incorporated, or
modified if they are incorporated into
Medicare.2
Key Features of the FEHBP
The FEHBP offers a wide range of plans with a variety of benefits. Although there are some adverse selection pressures in the system, these are surprisingly small considering the fact that the FEHBP by law is community rated (the same premium must be charged to everyone without regard to age and other risk factors) and that there are wide plan variations. The key features are:
1. A stable premium structure
Premiums and other enrollee costs have been kept well in check. For much of the FEHBP's recent history, premiums have risen no faster than those in the private sector; in many years, they have fallen below those of private plans and Medicare. As the Congressional Research Service (CRS) noted in 1989, the "rise in private sector premiums in the 1980s exceeds FEHBP's."3 Later studies have shown similar cost control. In fact, premiums have been quite flat. The average FEHBP plan premium rose 0.4 percent in 1996 and 2.4 percent in 1997. In 1995, the premium actually fell 3.3 percent.
2. Negotiated premiums in a competitive market
Unlike Medicare, the FEHBP does not pay fee-for-service providers according to a fee schedule and does not pay managed care plans according to a rigid formula. Instead, it invites plans to submit a package of benefits at a proposed premium, and then negotiates prices and benefits plan by plan. Each approved plan, along with competitors, is offered to federal workers and retirees. The FEHBP pays a percentage of the negotiated premium, up to a dollar limit.
3. Many competing private plans
The FEHBP plans include several offered by employee cooperatives and major unions. One reason these plans are popular is that they are organized by groups that actually represent enrollees rather than by health maintenance organizations (HMOs) or insurance companies that often perceive the enrollee as a passive buyer in an individual market. This feature could be particularly attractive in a reformed Medicare system. One might imagine, for example, plans offered through the American Association of Retired Persons, major unions, or even churches.
4. Information dissemination
The FEHBP has a comprehensive system of information distribution, complemented by a sophisticated system of information provided through consumer organizations, to help beneficiaries make choices. This could be a model for Medicare, which has been roundly criticized by the U.S. General Accounting Office (GAO) for its relatively poor information system.4
5. Negotiated service contracts
Negotiations on premiums and benefits are held between the Office of Personnel Management (OPM), which runs the FEHBP, and individual plans. For HMO and point-of-service (POS) plans, the OPM typically starts its negotiations based on the local market for these plans; it does not, as in the case of Medicare, apply a formula based on the local fee-for service market. In the case of fee-for-service and preferred provider organization (PPO) plans, the OPM negotiates a fixed profit per subscriber, usually between 0.5 percent and 0.75 percent of premium. Thus, plans make money through negotiated service contracts rather than traditional profits. Although these plans have to accept market risk, they must lodge revenue surpluses in special reserve accounts that can enable them to bid more competitively in future years. This variation of the normal market answers many of the concerns voiced against allowing competing private plans in Medicare.
6. Low overhead costs
The FEHBP indicates that a large national program for millions of people, with a wide variety of plans and benefits and careful negotiations between the government and the plans, can be run with a fraction of the staff now running Medicare. As Reischauer notes, the OPM "accomplished the task [of running the FEHBP] in 1996 with a staff of fewer than 150 full-time equivalent employees and a modest administrative budget of around $20 million."5
7. Less regulatory control
Those who choose plans in the FEHBP are not locked into a comprehensive government-standardized benefits package. There are no premium caps on private insurance plans. There is no Department of Defense-style system of competitive bidding to determine which private plans can or cannot compete for employees' dollars. There are no government boards or panels setting rigid standards for the quality of medical care or specifying the value of a doctor's labor in the delivery of medical services. Private insurance companies, competing for each consumer's dollars, bear the lion's share of administrative costs, and the role of government bureaucracy and regulation is comparatively small.
Reforming Medicare to Incorporate Lessons from the FEHBP
Many of the these key features of the FEHBP should be incorporated into a reformed Medicare program, in some cases with changes that would improve on the FEHBP. Specifically, Congress should:
1. Create a semi-independent congressionally appointed board to operate traditional fee-for-service Medicare in all parts of the country. The board would have power to make variations in the benefits, including deductibles and co-payments, subject to an up-or down vote by Congress without amendment. This would give the traditional program more flexibility to modernize and compete with HMOs now in Medicare.
2. Require the traditional fee-for-service plan to include catastrophic protection and offer full Part A and Part B benefits at a stated premium, to be negotiated each year.
3. Change the government payment system to an FEHBP-style percentage of premium or health costs, but with the assurance that all the elderly and disabled receive enough assistance in the future to afford good care. The Physician Payment Review Commission (PPRC), which advises Congress on Medicare payments, in its 1997 report examined a variety of ways in which FEHBP-type payment systems could be applied to Medicare.6 The best structure might be to pay a percentage of the premium above a fixed dollar contribution, with a ceiling placed on the total government contribution linked to the cost of the area's traditional fee-for-service plan. In that way, those choosing a less expensive plan would have most or all of the cost covered, while an enrollee in the traditional program would know that he or she always would be able to afford that plan as well.
4. Invite initial bids from private plans meeting specified minimum requirements (including, for example, requirements on information disclosure and underwriting limitations). Then allow the Health Care Financing Administration (HCFA) to negotiate premiums and benefit packages, as well as service areas, with individual plans before agreeing on a final price-and-benefits package that is offered to Medicare enrollees in a particular area. Plans should have a basic core of benefits (as FEHBP requires), but negotiators should be able to develop a variety of plan benefits and prices in any area. The Medicare fee-for-service plan also should be required to offer a bid, with the price established through negotiations in conjunction with Congress.
5. Operate an annual open season in which retirees can choose a plan for the following year.
6. Experiment with risk adjusters to adjust payments to different plans according to the likely costs associated with the beneficiaries who enroll in them (something the FEHBP does not do). The PPRC indicates in its 1997 report that very simple methods could deal with many of the risk differences experienced by the plans.
Lessons of the FEHBP
Created by Congress in 1959, the Federal Employees Health Benefits
Program offers over 400 competing private plans to active and
retired Members of Congress and congressional staff, as well as
active and retired federal and postal workers and their
families-almost 9 million people.7 The FEHBP works well
despite some problems of enrollment and design, and these problems
could be dealt with easily in a redesigned Medicare program that
significantly improves coverage for the nation's elderly and
disabled.
The FEHBP population is not an ideal insurance pool. For one
thing, the FEHBP population of active employees is generally older
(43.8 years) than employees in the private sector (37.4
years).8 For another, enrollment is optional and
eligibility requirements are quite liberal. Also, plans may not
impose waiting periods, limitations, or exclusions from coverage
for pre-existing medical conditions.
Further, because the proportion of higher-cost federal retirees in
the program has grown steadily, the proportion of higher-cost
enrollees in the FEHBP has grown as well. In 1975, 858,000 retirees
comprised 27 percent of FEHBP policyholders; by 1992, some 1.6
million retirees accounted for 40 percent of
policyholders.9 The average age of those covered in the
program (which includes dependents) also has been increasing,
according to OPM actuaries,10 but the program's strict
community rating requirement prevents plans from pricing their
coverage differently for this higher-risk group.
How the FEHBP Works
Federal workers and retirees can choose from a variety of health
plans, ranging from traditional fee-for-service plans to insurance
plans sponsored by employee organizations or unions to managed care
plans. Approximately 40 percent of all federal subscribers and 18
percent of all federal retirees currently are enrolled in HMOs. All
HMOs in the FEHBP offer benefits, including catastrophic coverage
and mental health coverage, that are especially attractive to the
elderly. Almost all cover the care received in an extended care
facility, some with no dollar or day limits. No federal retiree has
a range of choice that includes fewer than seven
plans.11
The National Association of Retired Federal Employees (NARFE), the
major private organization representing federal retirees, declares
that "All FEHBP plans are good. All cover hospital and physician
care, prescriptions, outpatient diagnostic lab tests, treatment of
mental illness, home health care, routine mammograms for women over
35, routine prostrate cancer tests for men over 40, and stop
smoking programs." Unlike Medicare, most FEHBP plans cover
prescription drugs and include a wide range of dental services; in
addition, the elderly can choose very specialized items, such as
diabetic supplies.
How the Elderly Pick Plans
Each year, in preparation for the annual fall open season in which
retirees and regular employees pick plans for the following year,
the OPM sends beneficiaries an FEHBP Guide, which includes a
health plan comparison chart. Health plans also provide retirees
with information on benefits and premiums in a variety of ways,
including advertising. Perhaps the most valued consumer resource
for federal employees and retirees is Checkbook's Guide to
Health Insurance Plans for Federal Employees, which is
published by a consumer organization. The popular Guide
compares plans; gives employees and retirees general advice on how
to pick a plan; outlines plan features and special benefits;
presents detailed cost tables (including out-of-pocket limits for
catastrophic coverage); and provides customer satisfaction surveys
on the performance of plans. It also includes specialized advice
for federal retirees, including retirees with and without Medicare,
and information on HMO options and Medicare.
The Guide's customer satisfaction surveys are quite
detailed and allow workers to rate plan performance in such areas
as access to care, quality of care, availability of doctors,
willingness to provide customer information and advice by phone,
ease of getting appointments for treatments or checkups, typical
waiting times in the doctor's office, access to specialty care, and
follow-through on care. They also review patient experience with
such things as explanation of care, the degree to which the patient
is involved in decisions relating to care, the degree to which the
plans' doctors take a personal interest in the patient's case,
advice on prevention, the amount of time available with the doctor,
the available choice of primary care physicians and access to
specialists, and the speed with which the patient can contact the
plan's service representative.12
Federal retirees also receive additional guidance from NARFE,
which represents approximately 500,000 current and retired federal
employees. With a network of over 1,700 chapters throughout the
country, NARFE works closely with the OPM to answer questions and
resolve problems related to health insurance and retirement. In
preparation for open season, NARFE publishes its annual Federal
Health Benefits and Open Season Guide.13 Most important of all, it
rates plans on benefit packages that would be most attractive to
the elderly. NARFE ranks Alliance and Blue Cross/Blue Shield, for
example, as the best choices for prescription
drugs.14
The Role of the Office of Personnel Management
The FEHBP statute gives the OPM the authority to contract with
health insurance carriers; prescribe reasonable minimal standards
for plans; prescribe regulations governing participation by federal
employees, retirees, and their dependents, as well as to approve or
disapprove plan participation in the FEHBP; set government
contribution rates in accordance with federal law; make available
plan information for enrollees; and administer the FEHBP trust
fund, the special fund that contains contributions from the
government and enrollees, and from which all payments to health
plans are made.15
Unlike the HCFA, the OPM does not impose price controls or fee
schedules, or issue detailed guidelines to doctors or hospitals on
standardized benefits. Private plans within the FEHBP must meet
"reasonable minimal" standards regarding benefits,16 but
the law creating the FEHBP does not specify a comprehensive set of
standardized benefits. Congress merely defines the "types" of
benefits that "may be" provided.17
The OPM sends out an annual "call letter" in spring to insurance
carriers, inviting them to discuss rates and benefits for the
following calendar year.18 In these confidential
discussions, the OPM outlines its expectations on rates and
benefits to the carriers, and the carriers invariably respond by
offering proposals. This is an unusual, and largely successful,
mixture of discussion and jawboning. Congress rarely intrudes into
this process.
In setting the government contribution to retirees' health
benefits, the OPM must make its calculations according to a formula
established by law. The OPM determines the government contribution
on the basis of the average premium of the government-wide service
benefit plan, the indemnity benefit plan, the two largest employee
organization plans, and the two largest comprehensive plans. This
is commonly called the "Big Six" formula.19 The OPM
calculates the average premium of these six largest plans and
multiplies that average by 60 percent. This determines the maximum
annual government contribution, which is applied to each plan. This
maximum contribution in 1995 was $1,600 for individuals and $3,490
for families. The formula has one other crucial adjustment: In no
case can the federal government contribute any more than 75 percent
of the cost of any plan's premium. The federal contribution for
individuals ranges from about $1,000 to about $1,600. According to
the PPRC, premiums for individuals range from about $400 to about
$1,800.
The OPM prepares kits outlining rates and benefits for the coming
calendar year, disseminating information on the plans.
Beneficiaries then pick a plan during open season. The OPM
maintains an Open Season Task Force to help in making decisions, as
well as a hot line that retirees (or regular workers) can call
during open season.
The government's premium is sent directly to whichever plan is
chosen. For individuals, the premium contribution normally is
deducted from the enrollee's paycheck (for workers) or annuity (for
retirees) and sent directly to the chosen plan by the OPM, which
also helps retirees and employees settle disputed claims.
Adverse Selection
Even though the FEHBP has been successful, there have been two
persistent and interrelated problems associated with its design:
adverse selection and an outdated system of insurance
underwriting.
Adverse selection, an irritant for many years, is exacerbated by
the strict community rating requirement but has not undermined the
program. The OPM has taken steps to limit the variation in benefit
packages, to limit some of the risk selection, and (during the
negotiation process) to allow some plans with particularly generous
packages to eliminate some benefits. Even so, however, in its
exhaustive 1989 analysis of FEHBP strengths and weaknesses, the CRS
concluded that the program was structurally sound: "That FEHBP has
continued to `work' over the years, despite major changes in the
environment in which it has operated, reflects the soundness of its
basic design."20
Using the FEHBP to Reform Medicare
Transforming Medicare into a program similar to the FEHBP would
mean fundamentally changing the role of the federal government, and
more specifically the Department of Health and Human Services (HHS)
and the HCFA. It would mean that instead of setting prices, paying
for specific services, and regulating virtually every facet of the
system, HHS (like the OPM in the FEHBP system) would have only two
broad functions: calculating and dispensing a payment to Medicare
beneficiaries, to be used for the purchase of health care, and
overseeing a market of health plans approved for sale to the
Medicare population.
A new Medicare system conforming to this framework should be
designed to include four elements: (1) changing the government's
role, (2) changing the Medicare payment system, (3) implementing a
system for negotiating with competing plans, and (4) setting
standards for participation by a plan.
Element #1: Changing the Government's Role
In a reformed Medicare system based on the FEHBP, HHS would have
monitoring and payment clearinghouse functions similar to those of
the OPM within the FEHBP program. It would be responsible for
making disbursements to the plans selected by Medicare
beneficiaries, but it would not regulate the premiums of plans or
the prices of services. Nor would it run any plans, any more than
the OPM does. On the other hand, it would negotiate directly with
competing plans offered to beneficiaries on premiums and benefits.
Specifically:
A. The government would maintain the traditional fee-for-service Medicare plan, which would be available everywhere. It would no longer run that plan, however. Instead, Congress would establish a federally sponsored not-for-profit corporation to administer a Medicare Standard Plan. This corporation would be governed by its own government-appointed board and would offer the standard Part A and Part B Medicare benefits and charge a premium. Each year, however, the board also would present to Congress recommended changes in the services, premium, deductibles, and co-payments for the Standard Plan. These changes would have to be ratified by Congress in an up-or-down vote without amendment.
B. The government would allow private plans meeting certain requirements (described below) to submit bids to offer a set of services to the elderly. The HCFA, within HHS, would negotiate with each plan on benefits, premium, service area, and other questions, after which the plan could be offered to Medicare beneficiaries.
C. Like the OPM in the FEHBP system, the HCFA would conduct the annual Medicare open season in which private plans would compete for consumers' dollars. During open season, beneficiaries would choose their plan for the following year; before open season, each Medicare beneficiary would receive an information kit from HHS with standardized information on prices, benefits, and consumer satisfaction for Medicare-approved plans in their area, including the Standard Plan. Beneficiaries also would receive a selection form on which to indicate their choice.
D. Once the selection had been made, the HCFA would send the appropriate contribution to the chosen plan (described below). The beneficiary would be responsible for any difference between that amount and the premium costs, but could elect to have the government pay that difference and reduce the beneficiary's Social Security check (similar to the Part B option today). If no plan was selected, the beneficiary would be assigned to the Standard Plan.
Element #2: Changing the Medicare Payment System
There has been considerable interest in recent years in refining
how the government makes payments for the care of Medicare
patients. One concern withthe current system is that Medicare
appears to be overpaying many HMOs because of the payment formula
based on the cost of fee-for-service plans in an area. Another is
that the defined benefit nature of Medicare and its payment system
necessarily drives up cost. To deal with this second concern, many
policymakers and Members of Congress have argued for some form of
defined contribution; under this approach, however, an arbitrary
budgeted contribution could leave seniors with an unacceptable
degree of risk.
Fortunately, the FEHBP's payment formula and plan negotiation
system appears to be a good model to solve these problems. Some
combination of the following options should be considered:
Option A: A market-adjusted but government-set contribution to
plans
Although the FEHBP does not use a fixed contribution to make
payments to plans (it uses a percentage of the premium with a
limit), a modified contribution system could work in an FEHBP-style
Medicare program. Essentially, this would be a modification of the
average area per capita cost (AAPCC) mechanism used today to set
capitation amounts for HMOs under the risk contract program. The
law sets this fee at 95 percent of the estimated average cost of
fee-for-service care for Medicare patients in the area. It then
adjusts this rate for certain demographic characteristics such as
age, sex, Medicaid eligibility, and institutional status to
determine the capitation amount.
Under this modified system, the HCFA would calculate the
contribution amount for each Medicare beneficiary, using the
primary risk factors and income information, and an adjustment to
reflect the total Medicare budget for the year and the estimated
average enrollee cost of a weighted local basket of plans (based on
plan information supplied for the open season). The basket would
comprise typical plans, such as the Medicare Standard Plan, a
catastrophic/medical savings account (MSA) plan, a Blue Cross
standard plan, and a comprehensive HMO plan. This is a refinement
of the Big Six formula used by the OPM to set the government
contribution to the FEHBP. The calculation of the Medicare
contribution would be made after the plans had filed their
price and benefit information for the open season so that the
contribution reflects the market formula encountered by the
beneficiary.
The distinction between Part A and Part B would disappear under
this reform, and the budgeted net Medicare expenditure for the new
program's initial year would be divided by the number of eligible
individuals to determine a base rate for the contribution. In
future years, the combined cost of the contribution would be
adjusted in line with the Medicare budget to determine the base
rate for the year. This base rate then would be adjusted according
to three factors:
- Primary risk. The base rate would be adjusted according to the enrollee's age, sex, reason for eligibility (age or disability), institutional status, and end stage renal dialysis status.
- Local market variance. The base rate also would be adjusted to reflect a weighted average enrollee cost of a basket of plans offering certaincategories of benefits (see explanation below).
- Income adjustment. To incorporate the objective of income-adjusting the general revenue subsidy to the current Part B program, the portion of the base rate roughly equivalent to the government's net Part B contribution would be adjusted according to the beneficiary's income. The portion equivalent to Part A would not.
This payment system would link payments to the risk and income
of the beneficiary, and in that way would avoid much of the concern
that high-risk or poorer beneficiaries would shoulder too much of
the cost. Yet the incentive for individuals to seek out the best
value for money in plans would be strong.
Option B: A negotiated premium with a formula payment
A possibly more attractive variant is first for the HCFA to
invite bids and negotiate benefits and premiums, as outlined above.
Plans would have to contain a core set of benefit categories or
types of benefits, determined by statute, including catastrophic
protection. It should be noted that such a core benefit requirement
is materially different from a comprehensive
government-standardized benefit package in which levels of
benefits, and even specific treatments and medical procedures and
their duration, are set forth in meticulous detail.
A minimum contribution would be determined by the government,
based on the average cost of plans in the area. The HCFA then would
pay a fixed proportion of the premium above that minimum amount, up
to a limit linked to the cost of the traditional fee-for-service
plan in the area, which would have to submit a bid in the same
manner as other plans.
This modification would weaken slightly the incentive to seek the
best value for money because the enrollee would be insulated for
part of the cost above the base amount. On the other hand, an
individual would still be able to choose the traditional plan, with
the government ensuring that the individual's net premium payment
would be fixed.
Element #3: Implementing a System for Negotiating with
Competing Plans
If the HCFA were to negotiate with Medicare plans, as the OPM does
under the FEHBP system, ground rules for both private insurers and
government negotiators would have to be understood clearly by
private insurers and government officials. The OPM's negotiation
with a host of private insurance plans is sensitive and unique in
the processes of government.21
To participate in this negotiating process, interested private
insurance plans would be required to submit an application to the
HCFA or to the relevant government agency. These applications
should disclose qualifying information such as financial solvency,
certification by state insurance agencies as plans lawfully engaged
in the selling of health insurance coverage, the service areas they
cover, the benefit coverage they will offer, a description of their
delivery systems, and their premium charges. If plans disclosed
this information in a satisfactory fashion, meeting the basic
requirements, they would be qualified to enter into the negotiating
process with the government. Using the FEHBP-style model, qualified
plans would be required by law to offer a core package of benefits,
including catastrophic coverage, and these benefits would be
identified in terms of category or type (such as hospital and
physician services). Specific benefit levels, or co-payments,
deductibles, or coinsurance, would not be defined by statute or
prescribed by the HCFA in regulation. Benefit levels, or the
inclusion or duration of medical procedures and treatments, would
be left entirely to the negotiating process.
Government officials would have a legal obligation to negotiate
with private plans on a confidential basis. Negotiation would cover
such topics as the adequacy of coverage levels and alternative
combinations of benefits, the accuracy of proposed marketing
materials, the ease of consumer access to the plans' customer
service representatives, the presence of a dispute resolution
process for claims, and the reasonability of proposed premiums.
HCFA officials also would make sure that Medicare beneficiaries
would be able to contact any approved plan directly to get
additional information either on benefits or coverage. Like
officials at the OPM, HCFA officials would be expected to be
sensitive to changing conditions and opportunities in the health
insurance market and to be flexible in their dealings with private
insurance companies that must meet consumer demand in a highly
competitive environment.
If Members of Congress have serious reservations about the ability
of the HCFA-which is primarily a regulatory body-to carry out such
sensitive responsibilities, they may wish to detail OPM staff to
the task of negotiating rates and benefit levels for the country's
retirees, just as the OPM does today for retired Members of
Congress and federal workers.
Just as the OPM is responsible for enrolling federal retirees, the
HCFA would be responsible for enrolling Medicare beneficiaries. The
HCFA would be required to notify all Medicare beneficiaries of
approved plans in their areas in advance of a six-week to two-month
open season period. Any plan changes, such as disenrollment as a
result of death, would be the responsibility of the HCFA. Moreover,
new premium payments to health plans would be made by the HCFA and
would include both the government's share and the enrollee's share
(if any), and would be handled as a deduction from Social Security,
just as the Medicare Part B premium is handled today.
Element #4: Setting Standards for Participation by a
Plan
Any private health plan would be eligible to take part in the
Medicare program, providing it met certain requirements. These
requirements would apply to plans marketed by affinity
organizations, such as churches, unions, or elderly groups, not
merely to plans marketed by insurers or provider organizations.
There would be no restrictions on the number or types of plans
available in an area, and plans could operate in different service
areas and provide different benefits. A plan could gain approval to
market to the Medicare population if it:
A. Has a license to issue health insurance or operate a health plan in the state, or gains approval directly from HHS.
B. Will provide services in a service area acceptable to HHS.
C. Meets solvency requirements.
D. Includes a core of basic coverage determined by legislation. The basic package would have to cover medically necessary acute medical services-including physician services; inpatient, outpatient, and emergency hospital services; and inpatient prescription drugs-with a catastrophic stop-loss amount for these services. A plan thus could offer a much leaner package than today's Medicare (although it would have to provide catastrophic protection, unlike Medicare) while still offering a range of services beyond the base coverage. For example, some plans might offer dental benefits or drug coverage. States would be preempted from mandating additional benefits for plans serving the Medicare population.
E. Files with HHS a standardized statement of benefits; a table of rates for the same actuarial categories used to determine Medicare benefits (for example, age and institutional status); and consumer information as determined by an advisory board. Plans would not be able to deny coverage or change rates because of health status. The price, benefit, and consumer information also would have to be available to any Medicare beneficiary upon request.
F. Accepts and continues coverage for any Medicare beneficiary applying during the annual open season.
Issues Associated with the Proposed System
Under this reformed system, Medicare would operate in much the
same way as the FEHBP operates in serving retired federal workers
and retirees. Beneficiaries would be able to pick a private plan
that included the services they wanted beyond the core package,
with these services delivered in the way they wanted-perhaps, if
they wished, through an organization with which they were
affiliated (as many FEHBP enrollees do). Or they would choose the
Medicare Standard Plan. Because beneficiaries would receive a
defined contribution based on the options discussed earlier, they
would have a strong economic incentive to pick the plan that best
met their price, quality, and service objectives.
The organization of services, selection of benefits, and payments
to providers would be in the hands of plan managers competing for
enrollees. Unlike the federal officials managing Medicare today,
these managers would have the freedom and financial incentive to
experiment with new ways to deliver care at a competitive
price.
In stark contrast to the present situation, the HCFA would have no
role in setting the provider reimbursement rates, deductibles, or
cost-sharing levels of any private plan and no role in requiring
benefits beyond the care benefits required by statute. The federal
corporation, not the HCFA, would be responsible for these decisions
in the case of the Medicare Standard Plan.
Issue #1: Can a Consumer-Choice System Reduce
Costs?
Whether the proposed program reduces costs depends on how it
addresses two distinct aspects of cost. The first is total net
outlays of the Medicare trust funds: In other words, would it cut
the government's Medicare budget? The second is the gross costs of
serving the elderly: Would a trimming of government outlays merely
shift greater costs to the elderly, or would a consumer-choice
system slow down the growth in service costs? Linked to this second
question is another: Could the government's contribution be
designed so that it tracks, in a reasonably accurate way, the
market costs of serving enrollees with certain health conditions in
different places?
A defined contribution, in contrast to a defined benefit, controls
net government outlays directly because the total contribution is
determined by a budget. But would savings for government merely
result in extra enrollee costs? There are good reasons to expect
that this combination of market competition and enrollee incentives
would reduce the growth of total medical costs for, and hence the
financial exposure of, the elderly.
The FEHBP's premium and budget experience suggests strongly that
major savings could be achieved in Medicare with a similar market
based design, although conclusions have to be somewhat guarded
because there has been so little scientific research on the
program. In spite of its design shortcomings, the FEHBP generally
has outperformed both private-sector employer-based health
insurance and Medicare; in fact, it has outperformed Medicare by a
significant margin. In a comprehensive 1989 study, the CRS
concluded that cost increases were lower in the FEHBP than in the
private sector.22 Subsequent analyses have come to
similar conclusions.23 Analyzing the FEHBP's premiums in
the 1980s, for example, the health care econometrics firm Lewin-ICF
noted that "The available evidence suggests that the FEHBP
competitive market dynamics, combined with increased emphasis on
cost control, has outperformed the private sector despite
increasing benefits in recent years and the impact of an increasing
share of retirees."24 In 1995, health benefits expert
Frank McArdle concluded that the rate of premium increase had been
lower for the FEHBP than for the private
sector.25
During the 1990s, the FEHBP's premium performance has been
remarkable. In 1994, the average annual premium increase was only 3
percent, and 40 percent of all enrollees, including retirees, saw
decreases in their premiums. In 1995, the entire program
experienced an average annual decrease in premiums of 3.3
percent. More recently, premiums have risen by an average of 0.4
percent in 1996 and 2.4 percent in 1997.
Another reason to feel confident about converting Medicare into a
system of competing and flexible plans is that the current system
is so far behind other sectors in introducing design innovations.
Enrollment in HMOs is growing but still small, for example, while
PPOs are heavily restricted and point-of-service plans have become
available only recently. Even though the very elderly currently
enrolled in Medicare might be disinclined to switch to different
service arrangements, more recent retirees and the disabled
typically are quite familiar with new kinds of health plans
because of their experience during their working years.
These elderly likely would choose plans containing service
innovations if they had the incentive to do so, just as large
numbers of FEHBP enrollees do today. With so much ground to make
up, giving Medicare beneficiaries the incentive and opportunity to
enroll in plans using less costly arrangements could reduce the
growth in total costs sharply. One recent study estimates that an
increase of 10 percentage points in HMO market share within
Medicare would be associated with a decrease of 1 percent to 3
percent in aggregate Medicare spending.26
The FEHBP obviously does not operate in a market devoid of
government efforts to regulate prices. Government managers
negotiate premiums before they are posted for the open season, and
some who view consumer-based approaches with skepticism suggest
that this means the "price maker" power of a government buyer
actually holds down costs because plans are afraid of losing access
to their market.27 Nonetheless, the plans still must
design and price their product shrewdly, competing strongly with
each other for enrollees, if they are to remain in business.
Significantly, the OPM devotes most of its negotiating energy to
the large plans that undermine the government's maximum
contribution, and generally ignores the pricing of other plans, so
it is not clear that the government's jawboning function is more
important than this competition for price-sensitive enrollees in
holding down costs. What is clear is that the OPM's bargaining with
competing plans is far more successful at holding down costs than
is the HCFA's issuing of edicts to hospitals and physicians.
Enrollee Costs in Local Markets
The enrollee's financial exposure is affected by the local
market, not just by the economics of the system as a whole. To keep
this exposure reasonable, the contribution amount must closely
track the local market cost of serving an individual with the
enrollee's health care needs.
The closest equivalent to this in Medicare today is the AAPCC that
is used to pay HMOs in the system. This method of determining the
capitation amount has been criticized for a number of shortcomings
which blunt potential savings to Medicare and make the market less
efficient.28 For example, all HMOs in an area are paid
the same capitation rate linked to fee-for-service costs. In some
cases, this is more than Medicare would pay for a particular
enrollee in fee-for-service, so HMOs frequently can game the system
by attracting lower-cost enrollees for any given capitation amount
and keeping the difference in cost (subject to profit controls).
These and similar problems have led several experts to call for
greater flexibility in setting the AAPCC, as well as for
incorporation of more sophisticated risk
adjustments.29
A defined contribution approach can deal with these deficiencies
because it introduces an incentive that is very different from that
of the risk contract system. Because it represents a degree of
financial support for an enrollee choosing between plans with
different prices, not a full payment made to a plan, it triggers a
much stronger price/quality competition between plans seeking
enrollees. Plans would not be able to price themselves to take
advantage of the shortcomings in a bureaucratic structure of
capitation payments; instead, they would have to compete to satisfy
a customer who is motivated to pick a plan according to the full
package of premium, services, quality, and anticipated
out-of-pocket costs.
Issue #2: Is Adverse Selection a Serious
Problem?
Policymakers naturally are concerned about the possibility that
adverse selection might destabilize a consumer-choice Medicare
system, particularly a system like the one proposed here that
allows plans to vary benefits.
The proposed system, without any special risk-adjustment mechanism
in addition to the primary risk factors used for the contribution
and premiums, would result in a stable market with acceptable
differences in cost. Nevertheless, it would be wise to establish a
review commission to monitor this aspect of the program and to
recommend additional risk adjusters if necessary. There is little
research available on how problematic undesirable adverse selection
might be in a reformed Medicare program, but there are reasons to
suppose it would not be severe.
Perhaps the most persuasive reason for optimism is the experience
of the FEHBP. The community-rated FEHBP permits plans to offer a
wide range of benefits, yet requires plans to charge a perfectly
healthy 19 year-old exactly the same premium as someone who is
chronically sick at 89 years of age. The FEHBP also has no special
risk-adjustment mechanism. This would seem to be an open invitation
to destructive adverse selection pressures; but even though there
clearly is some adverse selection in the program, it is remarkably
stable.
The proposed Medicare reform incorporates the features of the
FEHBP that help to withstand destructive adverse selection and
includes other features that improve on the FEHBP in this regard.
Three features are particularly important.
- First, it limits plan switching to once a year, using the same open season procedure as the FEHBP (in today's Medicare, an enrollee in the risk contract sector may switch after just 30 days). This would make it more difficult for enrollees to destabilize the market by transferring to generous, unrestricted plans just to cover an expensive illness or elective treatment.
- Second, it allows plans to vary their premiums according to a range of basic risk factors, which the FEHBP does not. This premium variation would reduce the financial attraction of seeking out enrollees who are likely to be healthier because of their demographic characteristics. Adjusting the contribution according to the primary risk categories also would insulate enrollees in higher risk categories from their generally higher premium costs.
- Third, it incorporates central marketing and information distribution arrangements (an elaboration of the FEHBP open season) to help limit cherry picking by plans. Because Medicare enrollees would receive standard information on all plans in their area, it would be impossible for plans to "hide" from applicants they do not desire; to retain their approved status and continue marketing to Medicare enrollees, plans also could be required to adopt other marketing guidelines to reduce unfair practices.
But if traditional Medicare continues as an option for
beneficiaries, as it should, would there be significant adverse
selection against the government because only very old and
chronically sicker beneficiaries remained with the plan? And would
these enrollees face spiraling net costs under the defined
contribution system?
Although both results are theoretically possible, especially if
the government-operated plan remains as inflexible and outdated as
today's Medicare system, the design of the proposed system reduces
this danger. For one thing, because every plan's premium would be
adjusted by the major risk factors, a plan attracting a large share
of very old enrollees would receive much higher premium income from
these enrollees, who, in turn, would qualify for a larger
contribution. For another, the contribution amount would be
adjusted in each area according to the weighted costs of a basket
of plans, which would include the Medicare Standard Plan, giving a
further refinement to the contribution and thus helping to limit
the potential for large net costs to enrollees in the Standard
Plan. Moreover, there could be a percentage contribution to
premiums in addition to a basic level of contribution, as suggested
earlier (and like the FEHBP system), so that enrollees who feel
they need more elaborate care would receive a larger
contribution-one large enough to afford the traditional
fee-for-service plan in any area.
Further, it is by no means obvious that chronically sicker
beneficiaries generally would avoid private plans in favor of the
Standard Plan. The private plans could not turn away any
beneficiary during open season, no matter how sick the person was;
and unless its structure of coverage was significantly changed from
today's Medicare, the Standard Plan would not provide stop-loss
protection and would lack coverage for services (such as
prescription drugs) that is routine in private plans.
Information, Marketing, and Consumer Decision Making
A final concern is information. For a market to function
efficiently and satisfy consumers, those consumers must be armed
with the information they need to make good decisions. Because
health care decisions can be confusing enough for young,
well-educated people, it is certainly reasonable to ask whether
elderly people-who often are easily confused-could make informed
decisions in a market of competing plans.
There is little research available on exactly what information the
elderly require to make sensible health care decisions, but several
categories are suggested. These include premium and likely out-of
pocket costs, benefits, information on customer satisfaction, and
some measurements of quality.30 In the information
clearinghouse function assigned to HHS, standardized consumer
information on prices and benefits would be included, as would such
information as categorization of plans (similar to the Medigap
market); typical costs for certain illnesses, perhaps using the
"illness episode approach"; and patient evaluations such as those
prepared for FEHBP enrollees by Washington Consumers' Checkbook. To
make this information as helpful as possible, it would make sense
to create a consumer advisory board, consisting of representatives
of Medicare beneficiaries and the health care industry, to
recommend to the HHS what information should be made available to
beneficiaries, and how. Plans would be free to supply additional
information and to advertise, as they can in the FEHBP, but they
would have to meet certain disclosure criteria to remain
Medicare-approved.
Conclusion
Congress's own health plan, the FEHBP, is one of Washington's
unsung success stories. For many years, it has given Members of
Congress, as well as millions of active and retired federal
employees, a range of modern plans and benefits unavailable to
Medicare beneficiaries. And it has done so while keeping costs
firmly under control. The FEHBP also includes tools for operating a
choice system that could be the model for long-term reform of
Medicare.
It is time to reform Medicare to make the same advantages
available to America's seniors.
1 Robert D. Reischauer,
Medicare Reform and the Federal Employees Health Benefits
Program, testimony before Committee on Finance, U.S. Senate,
105th Cong., 2nd Sess., May 21, 1997.
2 Much of the factual
information in this study is drawn directly from Stuart M. Butler
and Robert E. Moffit, "The FEHBP as a Model for a New Medicare
Program," Health Affairs, Vol. 14, No. 4 (Winter 1995), pp.
47 61, and the People-to-People Health Foundation, Project HOPE, http://www.projhope.org/HA/
.
3 Congressional Research
Service, The Federal Employees Health Benefits Program: Possible
Strategies for Reform, 1989, p. 255.
4Medicare Managed Care: HCFA
Missing Opportunities to Provide Consumer Information,
testimony of William Scanlon, U.S. General Accounting Office,
before Special Committee on Aging, U.S. Senate, 105th Cong., 1st
Sess., April 10, 1997.
5 Reischauer, Medicare
Reform.
6 Physician Payment Review
Commission, Annual Report to Congress, 1997, chapter
9.
7 For a detailed discussion of
the FEHBP, see Robert E. Moffit, "Consumer Choice in Health:
Learning from the Federal Employees Health Benefits Program,"
Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 878, February 6, 1992;
see also Walton Francis, "The Political Economy of the Federal
Employee Health Benefits Program," in Robert B. Helms, ed.,
Health Policy Reform: Competition and Controls (Washington
D.C.: American Enterprise Institute, 1995), pp. 269-307.
8 Based on a 1989 analysis of
private and public sector employee age factors, the difference in
age between federal employees and private-sector employees means
that federal employees would have health care costs averaging 22
percent higher than those of private-sector workers. Focus 89,
Proposed Changes in the FEHBP Program, CNA Insurance Companies,
1989.
9 Carolyn Pemberton and Deborah
Holmes, eds., EBRI Databook on Employee Benefits
(Washington, D.C.: Employee Benefit Research Institute, 1995), p.
278.
10 Information from Nancy
Kichak, Director of the Office of Actuaries, U.S. Office of
Personnel Management.
11 W. Smith, ed., Federal
Health Benefits Information and Open Season Guide, 1995
(Washington, D.C.: National Association of Retired Federal
Employees, 1994), pp. 14, 62.
12 W. Francis, ed.,
Checkbook's Guide to 1995 Health Insurance Plans for Federal
Employees (Washington, D.C.: Washington Consumers' Checkbook,
1994), pp. 49-79.
13Federal Health Benefits
Information and Open Season Guide, 1995, p. 50.
14Ibid., p. 63.
15 This summary of legal
authorities may be found in CRS, The Federal Employees Health
Benefits Program, p. 238.
16 For purposes of the FEHBP,
a health plan is defined as a "group insurance policy or contract,
medical or hospital service agreement, membership or subscription
contract, or similar group arrangements provided by a carrier for
the purpose of providing, paying for, or reimbursing expenses for
health services." Code of Federal Regulations, Chapter 16,
1602.170-8. The minimum standards for health benefits carriers
include a requirement that the carrier be lawfully engaged in the
business of supplying health benefits and meets financial solvency
standards, including "reasonable financial and statistical records;
open access to records by OPM and GAO investigators or auditors; an
acceptance of payment in accordance with contract and contingency
receive requirements; a requirement to perform the contract in
accordance with `prudent business practices.'" See 48 CFR, Chapter
16, Part 1609, "Contractor Qualifications." The OPM's other
regulatory prohibitions and restrictions deal primarily with
consumer protection, including prohibitions against false,
misleading, deceptive, or unfair advertising, and a requirement for
retention of financial records.
17United States Code,
Title 5, Section 8904.
18 In this process, the OPM
maintains strict confidentiality. OPM staff members historically
have not shared the document even with the Office of Management and
Budget.
19 In recent years, the
government-wide "service benefit plan" has been Blue Cross and Blue
Shield; the two largest employee organization plans have been the
Mailhandlers and the Government Employee Hospital Association Plan;
and the two largest comprehensive medical plans have been the
Kaiser Foundation Plan of Northern California and the Kaiser
Foundation Health Plan of Southern California. With Aetna dropping
out of the program in 1989, OPM staff members have used a
mathematical formula to calculate the service indemnity component
of the Big Six formula.
20 CRS, Federal Employees
Health Benefits Program, p. 231.
21 For advice on establishing
the conditions of a negotiation process for private plans in a
reformed Medicare system, the authors are indebted to James
Morrison, formerly Associate Director of Compensation at the OPM. A
high-ranking career civil servant who supervised FEHBP negotiations
with private health insurance plans, Morrison served at the OPM
during the Carter and Reagan Administrations.
22 CRS, Federal Employees
Health Benefits Program, p. 231.
23 See Francis, "Political
Economy of the Federal Employee Health Benefits Program." See also
Allen Dobson, Rob Mechanic, and Kellie Mitra, Comparison of
Premium Trends for Federal Employees Health Benefits Program to
Private Sector Premium Trends and other Market Indicators
(Fairfax, Va.: Lewin-ICF, 1992).
24 Dobson et al.,
Comparison of Premium Trends.
25 Frank McArdle. "Opening Up
the FEHBP," Health Affairs, Vol. 14, No. 2 (Summer
1995).
26 Laurence C. Baker, Can
Managed Care Control Health Care Costs? Evidence from the Medicare
Experience (Washington, D.C.: National Institute For
Health Care Management, 1995), p. 22.
27 See Joseph White, "Managing
Health Care Costs in the United States," in Health Care Reform
through Internal Markets: Experiments and Proposals
(Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution, 1995), p. 148.
28 See, for example, U.S.
General Accounting Office, Medicare: Changes to HMO Rate Setting
Method Are Needed to Reduce Program Costs, GAO/HEHS-94-119,
September 1994. See also Jonathan Ratner, GAO, testimony before
Subcommittee on Health, Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of
Representatives, 104th Cong., 1st Sess., May 24, 1995.
29 See Gail Wilensky,
"Incremental Health System Reform: Where Medicare Fits In,"
Health Affairs, Vol. 14, No. 1 (Spring 1995), pp.
179-180.
30 For a discussion of this
issue, see Shoshanna Sofaer, "Informing and Protecting Consumers
Under Managed Competition," Health Affairs, Supplement 1993,
pp. 76-86.