The 2010 Dodd–Frank Act authorized the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) to impose new regulations on payday lenders and other short-term credit providers, and these rules will likely harm millions of consumers. The act compounded this regulatory burden by effectively creating a variety of taxpayer-subsidized alternatives to private lenders in this market. Supporters of Dodd–Frank argue that these changes are necessary because private short-term lenders tend to “trap” consumers in high-cost debt. This view is fundamentally flawed, and the federal government has no need to regulate short-term lenders, all of whom are currently regulated by state governments.
Payday Lenders Provide Valuable Services
Advocacy groups have campaigned against payday (and other short-term) lenders for years, claiming that these companies systematically “trap” people in high-cost debt.[1] Since Dodd–Frank passed in 2010, federal regulators are basing new regulations on this flawed premise. For instance, the director of the CFPB recently stated, “Too many short-term and longer-term loans are made based on a lender’s ability to collect and not on a borrower’s ability to repay.”[2] However, if lenders build their business on collecting money from people who cannot make good on their debts, they will soon find themselves out of business.
Furthermore, the CFPB’s own complaint database does not support the claim that there is a systematic problem in this industry. From July 2011 to August 2015, consumers lodged approximately 10,000 complaints against payday lenders.[3] Ignoring the fact that these are unverified complaints, the figure pales in comparison to the more than 12 million people per year using payday loan services. Certainly, some customers have legitimate complaints, but four years of raw complaint totals represent less than one tenth of one percent of the number of annual payday loan customers.[4]
Newly published survey results cast further doubt on the notion that payday lenders are systematically trapping consumers in debt. On the contrary, most customers knowingly choose to roll over their payday loan before becoming debt free, and they are even able to accurately predict when they will be debt free for one pay period.[5] While it may appear to some people that payday loan customers are making bad economic decisions, policymakers cannot make such judgments because the value in question is subjective. In other words, even though someone not connected to a payday loan may view the cost as “too high,” the borrower is the only person capable of making that judgment.[6]
APR Does Not Apply to Payday Loans
One common criticism of the industry is that payday lenders gouge customers by charging a high annual percentage rate (APR)—sometimes “upwards of 390%.”[7] This criticism is misplaced, in part because it misuses the APR concept. Properly used, the APR represents the actual rate of interest someone pays over the course of a year due to compounding, the process whereby interest is added to unpaid principal.[8] However, in a typical case, payday loan customers do not borrow for a full year, and the interest charges do not compound.[9] Thus, there usually is no APR on a payday loan.
For example, if a customer borrows $100 for two weeks, for a fee of $15, then the only way to appropriately express this fee as a rate would be 15 percent ($15 divided by $100). When a payday loan customer rolls over a loan at payday, he has to pay a new $15 fee and is then responsible for repaying a total of $130; the fee could then be expressed as a rate of 30 percent, and so on. Thus, interest costs cannot “explode” exponentially as they can, for example, with a home mortgage, since there is no compounding.[10]
Should the customer in this example roll the loan over more than 6 times, he would pay more in interest than the original $100 loan. However, this does not mean that the customer has been harmed. Such a criticism is particularly puzzling when made by federal officials since government-housing policies have, for decades, been geared toward increasing long-term mortgages for low/moderate income households. These mortgages can be criticized on precisely the same grounds, and they impose much higher total interest costs than payday loans.
Overview of the CFPB’s Proposed Rules
The CFPB’s current proposal creates two classes of short-term loans: those with up to 45 days in duration and longer-term ones that mature in up to six months.[11] For both categories, the CFPB has proposed two options, where lenders can choose between a prevention or protection framework. For the shorter-term loans, the prevention option requires lenders to apply the ability-to-repay standard.[12] This standard generally requires lenders to “make a reasonable and good faith determination based on verified and documented information that the consumer has a reasonable ability to repay the loan according to its terms.”[13]
If the borrower then defaults, he has the right to sue the lender for misjudging his ability to repay the loan. This option also creates a rebuttable presumption of an inability to repay either a second or third short-term loan within 60 days of the original loan. In other words, a lender cannot make another loan to the consumer within a 60-day period unless the lender can “prove” the borrower can repay. If the lender can rebut the presumption, it can provide no more than three consecutive loans without a 60-day cooling off period.[14] Combined, these two new provisions would severely shrink payday lenders’ profitability and ultimately shrink consumers’ access to capital.
Alternatively, a lender can choose the protection option, a framework that includes several screening and structural requirements. Using this option, the lender must first (among other requirements) verify the consumers’ income and borrowing history, as well as verify that extending a loan will not result in the customer being in debt “for more than 90 days in the aggregate during a rolling 12-month period.”[15] This option would impose a major change on the industry—currently, most payday lenders only require proof of employment and a bank account.
Once all screening requirements are met, the lender can provide only a loan that meets certain structural criteria, such as a maximum amount of $500 and a duration of no more than 45 days. The current plan would also require lenders to structure loans to “taper off the consumer from indebtedness.”[16] Longer-term loans face a similar set of new restrictions and, in some cases, have their interest rates and fees capped.
Title XII of Dodd–Frank Compounds Problems
Dodd–Frank places additional burdens on the industry because it creates several subsidized alternatives to privately provided short-term loans. Section 1204, for example, establishes federal grant programs to help FDIC-insured banks provide more “small-dollar value loans.”[17] Section 1205 authorizes similar grants for a wider range of entities, including nonprofit organizations as well as state and local governments.[18] Finally, Section 1206 establishes grant programs for taxpayer-funded groups known as community development financial institutions (CDFIs) to provide loans of up to $2,500.[19] Thus, the federal government is now subsidizing the competitors of the private lenders upon whom they are imposing high regulatory costs.
Conclusion
The Dodd–Frank Act authorized the CFPB to impose federal regulations on the short-term lending industry, and the agency is developing rules that will harm private firms and their customers. Furthermore, the federal government is now subsidizing these private lenders’ competitors. Combined, these changes will make it very difficult to for private business owners to serve their customers.
This new framework is based on the false claim that private lenders systematically prey on customers who cannot repay their debts. The evidence does not support such a claim, and the new approach is likely to prevent millions of people from gaining access to the beneficial credit products they currently use. The best way to ensure customers have access to low-cost credit is to foster private competition. The federal policies in Dodd–Frank take the opposite approach, and they are on the brink of shutting down many of the private firms that provide short-term loans.
—Norbert J. Michel, PhD, is a Research Fellow in Financial Regulations in the Thomas A. Roe Institute for Economic Policy Studies, of the Institute for Economic Freedom and Opportunity, at The Heritage Foundation.