(Archived document, may contain errors)
173
April 3, 1992
THE PRIVATE PROPERTY RIGHTS ACT: FORCING FEDERAL REGULATORS TO OBEY THE BILL OF RIGHTS
INTRODUCTION It is time for federal regulators to obey the Bill of Rights. This is the message of the Private Property Rights Act (S. 50), inft-oduced in the Senate by Steve Symms, the Idaho Republican. Symms's bill would give teeth to the Fifth Amendment's requirement that no "private property be taken for public use, with- out just compensation." Targeted by the bill is the mounting practice of govern- ment regulations to deprive individuals and businesses of the use of their property without compensating the owners for the loss of their property. Ile Symms bill would codify and make permanent Executive Order 12630, signed by Ronald Reagan in 1988, which requires federal agencies to consider whether their actions might infringe on property rights and, if they do, to seek al- ternative ways to achieve their goals. The Symms bill also would give the Presi- dent a legislative weapon to use in his fight to make all federal agencies fully and consistently put the right of property ahead of the power of bureaucrats. Just Compensation. The Fifth Amendment's requirement that when the gov- ernment takes private property the government must compensate the owner is re- ferred to interchangeably as the "Just Compensation Clause," the "Eminent Do- main Clause," or the "Takings Clause." Thus, if the government needs land on which to build a road, it must pay the owner for the land. The Fifth Amendment also applies to other infringements of property rights that fall short of total confis- cation; on these, however, the courts have upheld the right to compensation only inconsistently. In recent years property owners have found the use and enjoyment of their prop- erty more and more restricted by regulators, often in the name of environmental protection. Thus, for example, individuals have bought land for houses only to be told that they are no longer allowed to build. Farmers have bought land for farm- ing only to be told that they are not allowed to farm because their land must be left in its natuml state. Businesses have been told to shut down mining opemtions not, as it turns out, to prevent them from polluting, but because their mining prop-
erty has been designated as a "wetland" that must be preserved. Typically in such cases, the government has not voluntarily compensated the owners for their losses. Shift in Court. Since 1987, however, the Supreme Court has started to recog- nize that regulation is often used as a substitute for the power of eminent domain: Instead of buying land outright, the government often tries to avoid the require- ment of paying compensation by simply commanding property owners to use their land in whatever manner the government wishes. In the face of this practice, however, the Supreme Court has begun to hold that regulation, as much as out- right confiscation, can be subject to the constitutional requirement of just compen- sation. In response to this shift in the Supreme Court's treatment of regulatory tak- ings, Ronald Reagan in 1988 issued Executive Order 12630, which requires fed- eral agencies to determine in aavance if their actions may prompt a claim for com- pensation. The purpose of the Order is twofold: to protect private property owners from the inadvertent, de facto confiscation of their property through regulation, and to control and limit the amount that taxpayers have to pay in just compensa- tion awards to people whose property has been taken by federal regulation. Such awards will soon become a major budget item. The total amount of an such out- standing claims is over one -billion dollars and growing rapidly. The Executive Order has been applied diligently by some government agencies but has been resisted by others. A future President, moreover, could rescind the order. Symms's bill would make permanent the protection offered by the Execu- tive Order and require that the Attorney General certify that each agency is in compliance with the Order's principles. Ile Symms legislation could be improved if it required that compensation be paid out of the budget of the agency at fault in taking private property without compensation. This would give agencies a strong incentive to avoid unnecessary takings of the property rights of the citizens.
THE FIFTH AMENDMENT
The federal government and the states have the power to condemn and take over land for such public uses as roads, parks, post offices, or military bases. The Fifth Amendment to the U.S. Constitution stipulates that in such cases, which are called "takings," the owner must be compensated for the loss of the property. As the Supreme Court has explained, "The Fifth Amendment's guarantee that private property shall not be taken for a public use without just compensation was de- signed to bar Government from forcing some people alone to bear public burdens which, in all fairness and justice, should be bome by the public as a whole."I Since the general public thus benefits, the Court has declared, "the public at large, rather than a single ner, must bear the burden of an exercise of state power in the public interest.'sw
1 Armstrong v. United States, 364 U.S. 40,49 (1960). 2 Agins v. City of Tiburon, 447 U.S. 255,260-61 (1980). Although the Just Compensation Clause in the Fifth Amendment is mainly con- cerned with land, it applies to any kind of property. Example: If in a military emergency the government were to confiscate airplanes or ships from private owners, or simply require that they be turned over to the government for the dura- tion of the emergency, the government would have to compensate the owners. Government can take an interest in property short of complete ownership, more- over, and still be required to pay compensation for what it has ta 'ken. Thus, for ex- ample, where flights of government aircraft over private property are so low and frequent as to constitute a direct and immediate interference with the use and en- joyment of the land, the government has taken a flight easement for which it must pay damages to the landowner.3
REGULATORY TAKINGS
The government also takes property rights by imposing restrictions on the use of property. Suppose, for example, the government wants to preserve a forest or a wetland in its natural condition, either for recreational use or for a wildlife refuge. If the government were to condemn the land outright, there would be no question about its obligation to compensate the landowner. Yet, suppose further that the government decides to leave legal title to the land with its private owner and passes a regulation prohibiting the owner from develop- ing the land, or from farming it, or from doing anything else that changes the land's natural state. In this case the government would be compelling the private landowner to devote the land to whatever use the government desires. In effect, the government here takes away from the owner the right to use the land. The pri- vate owner of the land would be owner in name only; the effective owner would be the, government, although in almost all instances the private owner would still be liable for the payment of property taxes on the land. This would be an attempt to circumvent the Fifth Amendment and to achieve the same ends as would out- right condemnation, but without paying compensation. Comnwn Law Rights. Not all regulations, of course, infringe on private prop- erty rights. Under the common law of property and tort, a landowner's property rights are defined and limited by the property rights of his neighbors. If a regula- tion merely prevents someone from engaging in activities that would violate the rights of others under the common law of nuisance or trespass,4 such as polluting a river that runs through a neighbors's land, then the landowner has no right to compensation, even though the value of the landowner's land may be diminished as a result of the prohibition. This is because the landowner has no right to engage
3 United States v. Causby, 328 U.S. 256,267 (1946). 4 'Me common law kept clear the important distinction between inflicting a harm and withdrawing or denying a benefit. In general, only physical invasions counted as injuries and could give rise to a cause of action. See Richard A. Epstein, Takings: Private Property and the Power of Eminent Domain (Cambridge. Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1985), pp. 107-125. in such activities to begin with.5 Regulations in such cases actually would protect private property rights. The Easement Option. By contrast, if a particular activity would not violate the property rights of others as defined under the common law of trespass or nui- sance and would not give others any legal ground to sue, then a landowner has the right to engage in the activity on his or her own land. If a neighbor wants to prevent the landowner from engaging in some activity that does. not violate the neighbor's property rights, the neighbor must pay the landowner to abstain from the activity; and if the neighbor wants to stop the activity permanently, he or she must purchase an easement from the landowner.6 This means that any regulation that prevents people from engaging in activities on their land that do not violate the property rights of others abridges the property rights of the landowners whose activities are restricted. Specifically, such a reguIa- tion takes away some of the landowners' rights in the use and enjoyment of their land, in effect taking an easement that should have been theirs to sell. Even if many other desirable uses are still permitted to the landowners, the regulation is a partial taking. As such, the landowners deserve to be compensated for whatever property rights they have lost. Computing Compensation. Whenever a regulation takes away private prop- erty rights, the proper measure of compensation is the difference between the value of the property with and without the regulation; this difference is the value of the easement the government has taken. Of course, if the property is worth just as much with the regulation as it is without it, then no loss in value has been caused, and no compensation is owed. Similarly, some government actions may reduce the value of land without taking away property rights, and hence do not give rise to an obligation to compensate. Example: A decision to close an exit along a particular highway, or to build a new highway someplace else, may dimin- ish the value of hotels and restaurants along the original highway. If the landowners' property rights in the use of their land have been left fully intact, however, then they are not entitled to compensation out of taxpayer funds. The mere fact that a regulation amounts to a taking does not mean that the gov- erment cannot go forward with the planned regulation. It simply means that the government must pay compensation in order to do so. The only issue properly in- volved in regulatory takings cases under the Fifth Amendment is the right to com- pensation, not the validity of the regulations.
5 See, eg., Office of Legal Policy, U.S. Department of Justice, Economic Liberties Protected by the Constitution, March 16,1988, pp. 7-11, 32. 6 An easement is a right over the property of another. An affirmative easement is a right of use. such as a right of way allowing one to pass over the land of another to access a road or a beach, or a right to discharge water onto neighboring land. A negative easement is a restriction on the use of land by its owner, prohibiting him from doing something which would otherwise be lawful. A negative easement may also be called a "restrictive covenant" or a "negative servitude." Black's Law Dictionary, Fifth Edition (St. Paul, Minn.- West Publishing Company, 1979). pp. 457-58,1182,1229.4
PROBLEMS IN THE CASE LAW
Although the Supreme Court has recognized for at least 70 IT ars that regula- tions can constitute a taking of private property for public use, it has awarded compensation only rarely. Often the Court found procedural or technical reasons to avoid ruling on regulatory taking claims. In many cases, the Court has denied compensation on the ground that the regulation is an exercise of the "police power" of the federal government or of the state governments, even though the Fifth Amendment contains no "police powee'exception.8 Police power originally referred only to government action that sought to guard against genuine threats to health, safety, or property. Examples of this might in- clude zoning laws that ban toxic waste dumps or nuclear reactors from residential areas. Over the years, however, the term "police power"has been expanded to cover virtually any government action. As a result, any action that is for a public use or purpose usually constitutes an exercise of the police power in the eyes of the court. In cases in which the plaintiff seeks to invalidate a regulation, the "police powee'doctrine can be appropriate.9 But it is not appropriate in cases where the plaintiff is merely seeking compensation. The fact that a regulation that takes pri- vate property rights may fall within the police power, as that power has come to be defined by the courts, only suffices to show that the regulation is consistent with the Fifth Amendment's requirement that takings be for public use; it cannot eliminate the nuirement that just compensation be paid. Before it clarified mat- ters in 1987,1 the Supreme Court often acted as though the issue before it was whether a regulation was valid, when in fact the proper constitutional issue was whether a constitutionally valid regulation nonetheless required payment of just compensation. Confusing the Issue. The Supreme Court also has held sometimes that a regula- tion is not a taking of property unless the regulation leaves the Mperty owner with no remaining "economically viable use"' of his property. I Thishasmeant
7 Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon. 260 U.S. 393 (1922). The Court considered but rejected a regulatory Wdng claim some 35 years earlier in Mugler Y. Kansas, 123 U.S. 623 (1887). 8 For examples of regulations do have been upheld on "police power'" grounds, see Office of Legal Policy, op. cit., p. 35; Epstein, op. cit., pp. 112-15,121-25,130-34,140-41. 9 For example, in Village ofEuclid v. Ambler Realty Co., 272 U.S. 365 (1926), the first case to uphold zoning . st a constitutional challenge, the plaintiff did not even seek just compensation under the Fifth ondment in his appeal before the Supreme Court (although he had sought just compensation in the courts below), but instead merely sought an injunction against enforcement of the zoning ordinance on the ground that it took his property without due proms of law, in violation of the Fourteenth Amendment. 10 See Keystone Bituminous Coal Ass'n v. DeBenedictis, 480 U.S. 470,491 n. 20 (1987). 11 E.g., Agins v. City of Tiburon, 447 U.S. 255, 260 (1980); United States v. Riverside Bayview Homes, Inc., 474 U.S. 121, 127 (1985). Other cases have explicitly or implicitly rejected this view. E.g., Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon, 260 U.S. 393 (1922); Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CAW Corp., 458 U.S. 419 (1982).71be Court has never specified just how remunerative a remaining use must be in order to count as "economically viable." that a regulation must render the affected property essentially worthless before the Supreme Court will recognize a taking and award compensation. In these cases, the Court seems to have confused the issue of whether a taking has occurred with the issue of how much should be paid as compensation. Obviously, if a regulation leaves a property owner with some remaining "eco- nomically viable use" of his property, then the owner is not entitled to receive the full pre-regulation value of his property as compensation. The owner is entitled, however, to compensation for the drop in value resulting from the regulation, re- gardless of whether the property's remaining value is great or small, so long as it is less than the pre-replation value. There is a middle ground between paying the full value of the affected property as compensation and paying nothing. This mid- dle ground consists of paying the value not of the property in its entirety, but of the easement that defacto has been taken.
REVERSING THE TREND
In 1987 the Supreme Court's treatment of the Fifth Amendment's Just Compen- sation Clause began to change significantly. First, the Court made clear that the "police powee'doctrine, which it often had used to uphold the validity of statutes, does not apply to takings claims brought under the Fifth Amendment, and hence does not constitute an exception to the Just Compensation Clause. 12 The Court also explicitly rejected the notion that the only remedy for a regulatory taking is invalida on of the regulation, making clear that gnpensation is an appropriate remedyli even for a partial or temporary taking. 1 The Court further explicitly recognized that easements are a form of partial taking of property that can arise in the context of regulation or a permit-application process. 5 Finally, the Court ex- plicitly rejected the notion that "economically viable use" of a landowner's re- maining property rights will always necessarily bar an award of just compensa- tion for an easement that was taken. 16
12 See Keystone Bituminous Coal Assn v. DeBenedictis, 480 U.S. 470,491 n. 20 (1987). 13 When the goverment formally seeks to condemn a piece of land, compelling the owner to sell, it institutes an eminent domain proceeding. When a landowner whose land has been invaded or restricted by government, but who has retained legal title in his land due to the government's failure to invoke the power of eminent domain, wishes to obtain compensation by compelling the government to buy the land (or at least an easement therein), he institutes an inverse condemnation proceeding. 14 First English Evangelical Lutheran Church of Glendale v. County ofLos Angeles, 482 U.S. 304 (1987). First English dealt with a temporary taking, but the underlying principle is equally applicable to permanent takings of partial interests in propeny. 15 Nollan v. California Coastal Comm'n, 483 U.S. 825 (1987). In Nollan, the Court found a taking where the California Coastal Commission refused to grant a building permit to owners of beachfront property unless they agreed to convey to the government an easement for public access to the beach over their land. 16 Nollan, 483 U.S. at 830, 834-37. See also Loretto v. Telepronwter Manhattan CAW Corp., 458 U.S. 419 (1982). Both of these cases involved regulatory actions requiring landowners to submit to physical invasions of their land or buildings by others. However, the principle of providing partial compensation for a partial taking should apply regardless of the nature of the easement taken. These rulings all made it easier for landowners whose property rights are taken by regulation to obtain just compensation, prompting an attorney with the Con- gressional Research Service to proclaim the emergence of "a court trend support- ing increased protection of private property against government controls."17 This trend appears likely to continue. The Supreme Court late last year agreed to hear two cases that will give i an opportunity to strengthen Fifth Amendment protections of private property. I h The more widely publicized of the two involves a South Carolina law that prohibits new building on oceanf:ront property. 19 In this case, a man had bought two beachfront lots in 1986 for a total of $975,000, plan- ning to build a house for his family on one lot and to build a house to sell on the other lot. Two years later, South Carolina passed a law prohibiting new building near the beach. This law has prevented the man from building a house on his land -even though such a house would pose no threat to his neighbors and would be no closer to the beach than many other nearby lots in the same development, in- cluding those on either side of his, that were built before the 1988 law was passed. As a result of the law, the two lots have been rendered virtually worthless. The fact that the Supreme Court has accepted the two cases leads many observ- ers to precUct that the Court will reinvigorate the constitutional right to just com- pensation. M Substantial Awards. The trend toward granting compensation for regulatory takings also has been reflected in the United States Claims Court, the special fed- eral court in Washington, D.C., that hears all just compensation claims against the federal government. In 1990, for example, for the first time ever, the Claims Court held that two landowners who had been denied permits under the federal Clean Water Act to use their land in various ways because the government had classified the land as a "wetland" were entitled to just compensation because the government failed to prove that the substances that would have been discharged into the wetlands would have lowered water quality.21 Ile Claims Court awarded the respective Indowners over $1 million dollars in one case LZ and over $2.6 mil- . 3 lion in another, specifically basing its decisions on the distinction between tor-
17 137 Cong. Rec. S684 (daily edition, January 14,1991) (statement of Senator Symms) (the identities of the CRS attorney and the publication quoted are not provided). 18 The Court heard oral arguments in both cases earlier this year. 19 Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council, 112 S. CL 436 (cert. granted Nov. 18, 199 1) (No. 91-453). 20 The other Fifth Amendment just compensation case that the Court has agreed to hear involves a challenge by the owner of a mobile-home park in Escondido, California to a local rent control ordinance. Yee v. City of Escondido, 112 S. CL 294 (cert. granted October 15,1991) (No. 90-1947). 21 In the vast majority of cases under the Clean Water Act, the decision to deny a landowner a permit to fill in a wedand has nothing to do with any polluting properties of the substance that would be used to fill the wetland; often this substance consists simply of dirt taken from one pan of the wetland and deposited onto another. See William G. Laffer 111, "Protecting Ecologically ValuableWedands without Destroying Property Rights," Heritage Foundation Backgrounder No. 840, July 15, 199 1. 22 Florida Rock Industries v. United States, 21 Cl. Ct. 161 (1990) (involving the mining of limestone). This case is now on appeal before the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit. 23 Loveladies Harbor, Inc. v. United States, 21 Cl. Ct. 153 (1990) (involving the building of houses).Mis case is
7
tious and nontortious uses of land. 24 In each case, it was clear that the decision by the Army Corps of Engineers to deny a permit under the Clean Water Act had nothing to do with the prevention of water pollution, but instead was motivated purely by a desire to preserve the wetlands in question as wetlands. Therefore, the Corps of Engineers was really confiscating an easement on the landowners' land, taking away some or all of their development rights. While these two cases are on appeal, there is Svidence that higher courts will side with property owners. In a bellwether case, 5 the Claims Court in 1989 awarded over $150 million to a company that had been prohibited by the Depart- ment of the Interior from mining coal on its own land. The Court of Appeals last year affumed the decision, and the Supreme Court declined to take the government's appeal, thereby allowing the lower court decisions to stand. The Su- preme Court's decision not to review the lower courts' rulings in this case is widely viewed as solid evidence that it will d5cide the cases currently before it in favor of justly compensating the landowners. 6
PAYING FOR REGULATORY TAKINGS
The increased ability of property owners to secure just compensation when their property rights are taken by regulations means that the government, and hence the taxpayers, can expect to pay more in coming years for actions that re- strict property rights. As a consequence of the court rulings of the past five years, and of the explosive growth in regulation over the past twenty years, the number of takings claims filed against the government, the frequency with which property owners seeking just compensation win, and the average dollar amount awarded to successful claimants all have increased. Consider the following: Or 52 cases alleging the taking of property and seeking compensation were filed with the Claims Court last year, the most in at least a de- cade, and possibly the most ever.27 1w Nearly 200 takings cases are pending in the Claims Court.28 The total compensation that the U.S. would have to pay if those seeking
now on appeal before the U.S. Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit. 24 See Florida Rock Industries, 21 Cl. CL at 166-68. The only damage that is done when a wedand is filled with chemically harmless material is to the landowner's own property, the wedand; there is no physical invasion of anyone else's land or water such as would give rise to a common-law nuisance action. See Epstein, op. cit., p. 123. 25 Whitney Benefits, Inc. v. United States, 18 Cl. Ct. 394 (1989), modified, 20 Cl. Ct. 324 (1990), aff d, 926 F.2d 1169 (Fed. Cir.), cert. denied, 112 S. Ct. 406 (1991). 26 Sm eg., Moore, "Showdown on Property Rights," National Journal, November 30, 199 1. p. 2940; "Environment Laws Face a Stiff Test from Landowners," The New York Times, January 20, 1992, p. A 1. 27 Ibid. 28 Ibid. redress were to win and receive the full amount that they are seek- ing is well over $1 billion. Although the United States surely will win and thereby avoid paying compensa- don in many of these cases, the frequency with which property owners seeking just compensation win has risen sharply in recent years. Property owners won more than half of all regulatory taking cases decided by the federal courts in 1990, the most recent year for which figures are available. In contrast, the federal government wins nine out of ten times in other areas of the law. The growth in federal regulation in the past three years, and the trend in the courts toward protecting private property owners, means that the government can expect to pay more in the future to compensate for regulatory takings.
EXECLMVE ORDER 12630
On March 15, 1988, in response to the Supreme Court's 1987 takings decisions and the perceived increase in the likelihood of the federal government having to pay increased just compensation awards, Ronald Reagan issued an Executive Order dealing with "GoverrLWent Actions and Interference With Constitutionally '29 Protected Property Rights.' This detailed Executive Order basically requires each department or agency in the Executive Branch: X to consider in advance whether any contemplated action might, under the Supreme Court's case law as it stands at the time of the agency's or department's determination, be a taking of private prop- erty, and hence lead to an eventual judgment against the U.S. that must be paid by the Treasury; X to estimate the potential cost to the federal government of any con- templated action regulating the use of private property, in the event that a court later determines that the action constituted a taking; X to look for alternatives that would achieve the same ends but would not involve takings or would impose less on private property; X to decide in advance whether a particular action that may result in a taking is worth what it is likely to cost; and X to set regulatory priorities. The Executive Order also gives the departments and agencies detailed and spe- cific instructions on how to minimize the burdens imposed on private property and the resulting liabilities imposed on the Treasury. These instructions include: X avoiding undue delays in granting or denying permits, and in mak- ing other decisions affecting private property;
29 Exec. Order No. 12630. 53 Fed. Reg. 8859 (M=h 18, 1988). ensggg that permits are granted or denied based on the same stan- dard;
ensuring that restrictions imposed on the use of private property are not disproportionate to the contribution of the restricted uses to the overall problem that the restrictions are imposed to redress. The purpose of all these measures is to avoid taking private property inadver- tently, and thereby to avoid incurring unanticipated costs to the taxpayers. Executive Order 12630 does not add to or alter the Fifth Amendment's require- ment that just compensation be paid, the probability that those landowners whose p is taken will be paid, or the amount that they will recover if they are paid. It simply requires Executive Branch agencies and departments to anticipate the potential fiscal consequences of their actions. Given the recent changes in the Supreme Court's standards for awarding just compensation, if federal officials fail to conduct such an inquiry before acting, they run a significant risk that the federal government will get stuck with an unex- pected bill several years later. This also would mean that the government could end up being compelled to pay for properties that it would not have chosen to buy if it had thought about its priorities in advance. Thus, the Executive Order is really just a "look before you leap" provision designed primarily to protect the taxpay- ers. It mainly is a budgetary tool-a device for controlling spending. Paying Costs of Regulation. Yet, the Executive Order also protects property owners. Since regulators will be forced to refrain from taking actions that they cannot afford to pay for, many regulatory takings of private property will be de- terred. Regulators no longer will be able to treat private property as a free good, usable without limit and without cost. Instead they will have to decide how much regulation they can afford. Thus, even though the Executive Order does not affect the ability of those whose property is taken to obtain compensation, it will still protect landowners. After all, landowners who have their property taken without their consent and who receive court-determined compensation ?I most always would prefer to forego the compensation and keep their land. There are two reasons why this is so. First, if the compensation provided were worth as much in the eyes of the land- owner as the property taken, the landowner would sell voluntarily, and the govern- ment would gain nothing by taking rather than buying. Second, com ensation is risky and uncertain, and difficult and expensive to seek and obtain. WTherefore,
30 Ibis requirement has been violated often in the past. The Army Corps of Engineers, for example, routinely abuses its enforcement authority under the Clean Water Act, which is purely an anti-pollution statute, by granting permits for discharges of materials that pose no threat to water quality only on the condition that the landowner set aside land for wildlife protection at his own expense. 31 Presumably even then they would still be entitled to receive compensation for any temporary taking that had occurred. 32 However, under the Uniform Relocation Assistance and Real Property Acquisition Policies Act of 1970.42 although court-determined compensation is better than nothing, landowners gener- ally would be better off if their land had not been taken in the first place.
BEYOND THE EXECUTIVE ORDER: THE NEED FOR A STATUTE
Although the Executive Order is a major step toward protecting private prop- erty rights, it lacks the force of law. Officers and employees of the Executive Branch have no statutory obligation to comply with the ordevr. Ahy President, moreover, may rescind the order at any time. Explains Senator Malcolm Wallop, the Wyoming Republican: But the order is not without shortcomings. It has no teeth. Without the possibility of judicial review or the requirement of disclosure, the executive branch can ignore the order with impunity. Moreover, as with all executive orders, it can be withdrawn on a whim.33
To date, some parts of the Executive Branch have been more diligent and enthu- siastic in complying with the Executive Order than others. Regulators in the EPA, for example, have resistV. the Executive Order because they view it as a threat to their ability to regulate. In practice, the easiest way to circumvent the Executive Order is routinely to find "no takings implications" when performing the "Tak- ings Implication Assessment" required by the Attorney General's guidelines for implementing the Executive Order. Existing Supreme Court and lower court pre- cedents are sufficiently open-ended to allow such a conclusion to be reached in many instances without an obvious breach of good faith. The Executive Order, meanwhile, does not limit the government's ability to regulate. The Takings Clause and the Executive Order allow regulation, but merely require that it be budgeted before the fact, in the case of the Executive Order, and paid for after the fact, in the case of Takings Clause. To strengthen the Executive Order and give it the force of law, Senator Symms introduced his Private Property Rights Act, S. 50. The Bush Administration strongly supports S. 50, and the Senate approved the bill last year. The House of Representatives, however, has not yet even considered the measure. The proposed legislation states that: No regulation promulgated after the date of enactment of this Act by any agency shall become effective until the issuing agency is
U.S.C. 4654(c), those who succeed in obtaining an award of compensation for the taking of property by a federal agency also receive, as part of their award, reimbursement for any "reasonable costs, disbursements, and expenses, including reasonable attorney, appraisal, and engineering fees," that they are forced to incur in order to obtain their compensation from the govemment. 33 136 Cong. Rec. S10917 (daily edition, July 27,1990) (statement of SenatorWallop). 34 Specifically, the EPA opposed adoption of the Executive Order, attempted to soften its requirements as much as possible, attempted to soften the guidelines for implementing the Executive Order, and actively lobbied against legislation aimed at reinforcing the Executive Order until the Administration had officially endorsed the legislation.
certified by the Attorney General to be in compliance with Executive Order 12630 or similar procedures to assess the potential for the taking of private property in the course of Federal regulatory activity, with the goal of minimizing such taking where possible.35 17his language would prevent any new regulation from taking effect unless the agency issuing the regulation: 1) has adopted procedures for assessing the potential impact of its regula- tory activity on private property, as required by the Executive Order; and 2) has had its compliance with the applicable procedures certified by the At- torney General. Not only would the Symms bill force the bureaucracies to take the Executive Order more seriously by putting conditions on their ability to regulate, but it would make permanent the protection afforded to private property by the Execu- tive Order. Executive departments and agencies would not be able to regulate until the Attorney General had certified their compliance with the applicable pro- cedures for assessing the impact of regulatory activity on private property. And the Attorney General cannot certify such compliance if such procedures do not exist. Ilerefore, no subsequent President could rescind the Executive Order with- out replacing it with something equivalent. By making the bureaucrats' ability to regulate conditional upon their compli- ance with the Executive Order, or with any similar procedures that might be adopted in the future, the legislation proposed by Senator Symms would give reg- ulators an incentive to respect private property rights. Holding Agencies Accountable. The Symms bill, however, goes only part way in defending the Fifth Amendment. To prompt regulators to take the greatest care when regulating property, for example, a bill could require all just compensa- tion awards to come out of the budget of the agency or department that had im- posed the regulations. Currently all such judgments come out of a "Judgment Fund" appropriated separately from any individual agency's or department's bud- get. The Executive Order requires the Office of Management and Budget to "take action to ensure that all takings awards levied against agencies are properly ac- counted for in agency budget submissions." But this requirement is not binding on Congress and may be repealed by the President at any time. Last year the Bush Administration proposed legislation that would require agencies and departments to reimburse the Judgment Fund out of their individual budgets, but not Represen- tative or Senator has yet inuoduced the Administration's bill.35 S. 50,102nd Cong., Ist Sess. 3 (1991).