Interest-Rate Caps—Like Other Price Controls—Harm Consumers

Report Monetary Policy

Interest-Rate Caps—Like Other Price Controls—Harm Consumers

July 27, 2021 12 min read Download Report
Norbert Michel
Former Director, Center for Data Analysis
Norbert Michel studied and wrote about financial markets and monetary policy, including the reform of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.

Summary

The best way for Congress to ensure that people get the credit they need is to improve the competitiveness of private credit markets, not to impose a ceiling on the rates that lenders charge. Interest-rate caps are price controls, and history has repeatedly demonstrated that they do not help the people they are supposed to help. Imposing interest-rate caps, such as those in the Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act, will restrict the supply of credit for those who most desperately need it, and ultimately raise the cost of credit for many other borrowers. Enacting price controls on such a widespread basis will worsen problems in credit markets, thus bolstering a false pretense for more price controls and government-provided credit. This policy route will ultimately increase people’s dependency on government and harm their ability to prosper.

Key Takeaways

Interest-rate caps are price controls, and history has repeatedly demonstrated that price controls do not help the people they are supposed to help.

Price controls destroy the effectiveness of markets and reduce opportunities to prosper. They can also worsen the conditions used to justify them in the first place.

Congress should not impose price controls on credit markets, and should avoid interest-rate caps like those included in the Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act.

Government controls on consumer prices—the maximum or minimum that companies are allowed to charge—are nearly as old as recorded history.REF For just as long, price controls have harmed people, especially those that the controls are supposedly designed to help.REF Yet, policymakers continue to promote and implement price controls as a way to help to improve people’s lives.

While trying to help people is a laudable goal, a decentralized price system is a key feature of a free enterprise system that allows people to satisfy their wants and needs better than a system controlled by politicians and bureaucrats who set arbitrary prices. Implementing price controls because some people view certain prices as “too high” does not change this fact. Price controls destroy the effectiveness of markets and ultimately reduce citizens’ opportunities to prosper.REF They can be particularly dangerous because they worsen the conditions that policymakers use to justify the controls in the first place. Unsurprisingly, some of the most prominent advocates for price controls are those who benefit the most due to reduced competition.REF

These realities apply equally to all forms of price controls, including the interest-rate caps that several Members of Congress are now proposing. Interest rates are merely the price that lenders charge borrowers for loans, and price controls have the same harmful effects in credit markets that they have in other segments of the economy. Congress should not impose credit-market price controls, including those in the Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act.REF If Congress wants to help people to provide and obtain credit more effectively, it should remove the countless regulatory barriers that stifle competition in the financial industry.REF

Price Controls Harm Those They Are Intended to Help

Market prices represent information on how people value products and services. This information is displayed as objectively as possible, and people use it to allocate (or ration) goods and services based on factors that include their own preferences, needs, and production costs. All else constant, businesses are willing and able to sell fewer goods at lower prices, while consumers prefer to buy more. Similarly, at higher prices, businesses prefer to sell more, but consumers are willing and able to buy less.

Price controls interfere with this process by replacing the price system with government officials’ subjective views. That is, rather than allowing consumers and businesses (the market) to allocate resources as objectively as possible, government officials ration goods based on what they think prices should be. Historically, usurping the decentralized price system in this manner has not worked. In the most egregious cases, such as those in the planned economies of Eastern Europe, price controls resulted in pervasive shortages.REF

Because experience matches the theoretical critique of price controls, economists generally oppose them. For instance, price ceilings create a legal maximum price. They tend to create shortages because business owners are no longer able to charge sufficiently high prices to provide products and services, and because consumers demand more than they would at higher market prices. Price floors, on the other hand, lead to surpluses because they prevent prices from reaching the lower level at which they would naturally settle. At artificially high prices, fewer consumers are willing and able to buy, while businesses are more than happy to sell.

Price controls have many harmful unintended consequences, including bribery and corruption to evade the controls, as well as rent-seeking, which benefits the people implementing the controls, but it ultimately raises costs for consumers and businesses.REF Moreover, they cause market distortions that provide additional pretense for more price controls and government intervention, both of which tend to further hinder the effectiveness of markets and decrease overall prosperity. Price controls rarely help the people they are intended to help—some people invariably end up with fewer resources than they would have had in a market-based system, and the highest income earners typically suffer the least, while the lowest income earners suffer the most.REF

Harmful Effects of Interest-Rate Caps

Caps on interest rates (usury laws) are price ceilings imposed to prevent interest rates from rising above an arbitrary maximum. Price ceilings on interest rates, just like price ceilings in other markets, do nothing to limit demand. In other words, while interest-rate caps make it more costly to supply credit, they do nothing to reduce the demand for borrowing.REF As a result, people develop alternate (more costly) ways of both supplying and obtaining credit, fewer people end up with credit than they would otherwise, and others pay more for the loans that they do obtain.REF

State usury laws have their roots in colonial times,REF and the U.S. has a long and unsuccessful history regarding various types of interest-rate caps. A federal price ceiling on bank deposit interest rates, for example, was a main cause of massive bank disintermediation during the 1970s and the 1980s Savings & Loans debacle.REF Similarly, prior to a 1978 Supreme Court decision that federally pre-empted them, a patchwork of state usury laws on consumer loans and credit cards restricted competition in these markets. Consequently, companies supplied fewer credit cards and (among other work-arounds) charged annual fees to avoid the rate caps.REF

Latest Federal Attempts to Impose Rate Caps

Many states still have their own usury laws, but these maximum rates typically apply only to relatively small consumer loans, resulting in a relatively limited effect on most consumers.REF Nonetheless, based on the false notion that private short-term lenders tend to “trap” consumers in high-cost debt, many federal officials have been increasing their efforts to restrict lenders’ ability to supply credit.REF The misnamed 2010 Dodd–Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act authorized the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) to impose new regulations on these lenders, and it also created a variety of taxpayer-subsidized alternatives to private small-dollar lenders.REF

Congress has imposed these regulations despite the fact that consumers want, need, and appreciate the credit providers in such markets.REF The combination of regulating private lenders while providing government-financed alternatives to short-term loans all but ensures a long-term reduction in consumer welfare. Congress is also trying to impose widespread rate caps by (among other endeavors) extending the price controls in the Military Lending Act to the broader credit market.REF

Price Controls in the Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act

The Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act (S. 2833) amends the Truth in Lending ActREF to extend the rate caps (and other restrictions) on certain loans for active-duty military personnel to all consumers. These features, enacted by the 2006 Military Lending Act,REF forbid providers of consumer credit to active-duty service members (and their spouses and dependents) from charging an annual percentage rate of interest greater than 36 percent.REF

Consumer credit, in turn, is defined via regulations prescribed by the U.S. Defense Department. Currently, these regulations define consumer credit as “credit offered or extended to a covered borrower primarily for personal, family, or household purposes, and that is: (i) Subject to a finance charge; or (ii) Payable by a written agreement in more than four installments.”REF The Military Lending Act also provide several exceptions, such that the rate caps do not apply to residential mortgages, automobile loans, or loans for other personal property when that property is used to secure the loan.REF The act applies the interest cap to a rate that includes all fees and charges, including those for single premium credit insurance.REF

If Congress enacts S. 2833, the new rate caps would apply to all credit cards, deposit advance loans, overdraft lines of credit, and various installment loans.REF The bill would, however, exempt loans made by federal credit unions. Congress should not impose price controls on credit markets, and it should avoid interest rate caps such as those included in the Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act. Price controls force businesses to impose higher costs on consumers and result in fewer people obtaining the goods and services that they need.

Conclusion

The best way to ensure that people get the credit they need is to improve the competitiveness of private credit markets, not to impose a ceiling on the rates that lenders charge. Interest-rate caps are price controls, and history has repeatedly demonstrated that they do not help the people they are supposed to help.

Imposing interest-rate caps, such as those in the Veterans and Consumers Fair Credit Act, will restrict the supply of credit for those who most desperately need it, and ultimately raise the cost of credit for many other borrowers. Enacting price controls on such a widespread basis will worsen problems in credit markets, thus bolstering a false pretense for more price controls and government-provided credit. This policy route will ultimately increase people’s dependence on government and prevent them from prospering.

Norbert J. Michel, PhD, is Director of the Center for Data Analysis, of the Institute for Economic Freedom, at The Heritage Foundation.

Authors

Norbert Michel

Former Director, Center for Data Analysis

Exclusive Offers

5 Shocking Cases of Election Fraud

Read real stories of fraudulent ballots, harvesting schemes, and more in this new eBook.

The Heritage Guide to the Constitution

Receive a clause-by-clause analysis of the Constitution with input from more than 100 scholars and legal experts.

The Real Costs of America’s Border Crisis

Learn the facts and help others understand just how bad illegal immigration is for America.