Every year, the federal government spends billions of dollars on social programs that are intended to help at-risk individuals, who are vulnerable to poverty and dependence on government safety-net programs, achieve self-sufficiency. Leading examples include employment and training programs ($18.9 billion in federal spending in fiscal year 2019); substance abuse treatment programs ($10.5 billion in FY 2017); and recidivism reduction programs ($68 million in FY 2015).
These and other social programs are intended to increase lasting well-being through the acquisition of education, skills, and other positive changes in behavior. They promise concrete change: for the unemployed, obtaining a job; for former inmates, lower rates of reincarceration; and for those with addictions, treatment that will enable them to live free from substance dependence. In contrast to other federal programs that offer transfer payments (e.g., cash, food, or housing assistance), these social programs are premised on helping individuals to build and maintain a meaningful and free life.
Unfortunately, most of these social programs have little to show despite steep expenditures. Many—particularly the “open grant model,” which is usually one of providing federal block grants to states for social programs—do not track whether federal spending produces key outcomes such as greater employment, reduced inmate recidivism, successful substance abuse treatment, and improved self-sufficiency. Even the data available from legislative attempts to manage program performance and distribute funds to “evidenced-based” services over the past two decades do not demonstrate that those efforts produce overall meaningful outcomes.
Meanwhile, “pay-for-success” efforts during the past decade, while showing some promise, remain largely outside the federal government’s main expenditures on social programs. Moreover, these efforts can be judged primarily by reductions in federal government expenditures, not direct impacts in building recipients’ capacity for self-sufficiency.
Overall, these federal social programs are not demonstrating that they achieve the outcomes for which they were designed. This both disserves recipients and shortchanges taxpayers. It is time for a transformation of federal investments in social programs, and this requires a new funding model. Federal policymakers should pay directly for outcomes in social programs in a way that truly respects the dignity of vulnerable individuals by expanding their capacity and adding to their well-being.
Summary of Current Federal Social Program Payment Models
Three principal methods are currently used by federal policymakers to distribute funds to social programs that seek to increase capacities among vulnerable recipients:
- The open grant model,
- The performance management model, and
- The social impact bond or pay-for-success model.
Each of these models has shortcomings. To achieve the goals of capacity-building among recipients, a new funding model is required.
This paper proposes a new payment model to bring about transformation in these social programs: the pay-for-outcome model. Before describing this proposed model, however, a review of the current models is provided.
The Open Grant Model
The open grant model characterizes many federal programs initiated as part of the 1960s Great Society as well as others that have proliferated since then. Federal executive agencies allocate these funds to states or directly to service providers according to the intended goals set by congressional legislation. One of the aspirations of the open grant model is to allow states or direct service providers to innovate in social programs based on distinctive local circumstances or the unique needs of the vulnerable individual.
Unfortunately, the vast majority of these initiatives do not produce convincing evidence that the programs work for their intended beneficiaries. There is often no serious data tracking or evidence that the outcomes for beneficiaries are achieved. As summarized by Yale University Law Professor Peter Schuck in 2014, “less than 1 percent of government spending is backed by even the most basic evidence of cost-effectiveness.”REF This use of federal funds is fundamentally flawed, representing both a misuse of taxpayer funds and a failure to keep the promises made to the vulnerable individuals whom federal policymakers seek to aid.
Three large federal block grants intended to reduce poverty exemplify the problems inherent in the open grant model. These include the Social Services Block Grant (SSBG); the Community Services Block Grant (CSBG); and the Community Development Block Grant (CDBG).
- The SSBG is a $1.7 billion-per-year federal block grant to states with five broad statutory goals intended to move individuals to self-sufficiency and eliminate dependence.REF States must identify their intended uses of the funds (over a quarter of which is spent on child protective services and foster care),REF but there is no consistent collection of outcome data that shows whether states achieve the SSBG program’s intended goals.
- The CSBG distributes nearly $700 million in federal funds annually to more than 1,000 local antipoverty programs through a state formula. The programs are duplicative, poorly targeted, and not funded on the basis of their achievement of measured performance outcomes. In 2019, the U.S. Government Accountability Office performed its most recent survey and audit of the data that the U.S. Department of Health and Human Services (HHS) collects on the efficacy of the program and concluded that there is little measurable evidence that this significant funding source achieves the goals that Congress intended it to achieve.REF
- Operated by Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD), the federal CDBG program spends $3 billion per year, $900 million of which HUD allocates to states. The CDBG was intended to provide housing assistance for low-income families, but its funds have often been funneled to high-income communities and to wasteful pork-barrel projects. For example, $500,000 from the program was spent to expand a brewery in New York,REF and $1 million was used to restore a Michigan hotel.REF
When not distributed directly to states, open grant model funds are distributed through federal agencies. The agencies outline the type of recipients they seek to assist and the general aims or activities that the recipients promise to undertake. In many cases, the federal agency overseeing the open grant does not track whether the services were supplied. Even when administrative agencies collect data from grant recipients, the data collection is focused on tracking provision of services, not outcomes for the beneficiaries. Grant recipients do not have to specify the intended number of services they expect to provide or the number of beneficiaries that will be reached per federal dollar expended.
Because open grants are largely distributed based on stated goals without outcome data collection and analysis, this model is unable to produce evidence that it achieves intended outcomes in the lives of vulnerable individuals. The overall persistence of the problems these programs seek to address suggests that they do not achieve those ends.
The Performance Management Model
Recognizing that the open grant model has significant flaws, over the past decade and a half a significant reform movement tried to improve the effectiveness of federally funded social programs.REF Federal legislators used program reauthorizations to implement the performance management model, which can take the form of three key reforms: collecting data on service provision and program performance, mandating that services deployed be supported by evidence, and requiring third-party outcome evaluations.
One of the most significant examples of congressional reauthorization that aimed to collect data and obtain performance analysis is the Workforce Innovation and Opportunity Act (WIOA),REF enacted in 2014 to replace the Workforce Investment Act of 1998 (WIA).REF In this reform, Congress attempted to move federal employment and training (E&T) programs from the open grant model to an evidence-collection and performance management model. The WIOA created a common performance accountability system for six core E&T programs. Despite that, in a 2019 report on the overall effectiveness of these government training programs, the White House Council of Economic Advisers concluded that “government job training programs appear to be largely ineffective and fail to produce sufficient benefits for workers to justify the costs.”REF
Another example of service data collection and outcome feedback based on available performance metrics is the Substance Abuse Prevention and Treatment (SAPT) Block Grant, which is intended to combat substance abuse.REF The main source of data to track these funds is the Treatment Episode Data Set (TEDS), a national data system of publicly funded substance abuse treatment facilities’ admissions and discharges.REF Again, this system attempts to track provision of services, not outcomes for individuals at risk of continuing addiction or, in the worst case, death through overdose. The Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration (SAMHSA) within HHS also used the Performance Management Reporting Tool (PMRT) to review the effects of these funds, but “there is no empirical evidence that such feedback leads to an improvement in performance.”REF
A second key aspect of the performance management model is the requirement that direct service providers deliver “evidenced-based” services, meaning that the program should be able to provide only services that have been evaluated and shown to have made a positive, statistically significant difference for the beneficiary. Unfortunately, many “evidence-based” programs fail to produce outcomes as intended. Generally, “evidence-based” programs are approved after investigators test the effect of services at an original demonstration site.
The evidence-based paradigm involves a presumed linked chain leading from random control trials to a flourishing social program sector. In reality, however, each link in this chain is weak. Overall, the paradigm rests on the following sequence of questionable assumptions:
- In any given field, a small number of programs can be evaluated by random control trials (RCTs); among the small set of trials, a number of clearly successful programs will be found.
- These successful programs can be studied and then serve as “model” programs that can be replicated across the relevant social program sector.
- The “replicated” versions of the programs will perform as effectively as the original RCT-tested versions.
- Replicated models will readily displace other older programs.
- A desirable level of effective service delivery will thereby be established and maintained throughout the sector even though the operation of most individual providers will not be meaningfully measured or tested.
The evidence-based paradigm is inadequate for at least six reasons.
First, at any given time, there are thousands of individual social programs in operation in a wide variety of fields such as drug treatment, anti-recidivism, and employment services. How policymakers determine which services are evidenced-based is normally based on a single demonstration of results, which can be subject to “single-instance fallacy.”REF RCT experiments will probably examine no more than a dozen of these thousands of operations each year. Only a small fraction of those evaluated will be found to have significant effects, and those effects will often be modest. It is therefore unlikely that a handful of RCT evaluations can uncover many “hidden gems” within this myriad of programs.
Second, the performance management model also runs afoul of replication fallacy: a common assumption that if a program can be evaluated and proven to have results in the initial location, scaling up or replicating the original method in another location is both possible and advisable. Most RCT evaluations are like “black boxes.” Although some programs appear successful, it is often unclear why they succeeded, and the most important factors behind their success (such as a charismatic leader) are not measurable. Even positive studies do not guarantee that cloning those programs and replicating them throughout the country will prove to be successful.
Third, even when an evaluation documents a highly successful model program, history suggests that it is nearly impossible to replicate that model effectively in other locations. Where there is evidence of original single-instance effectiveness and subsequent studies of wider implementation, the broader program results often do not live up to the promise of the original demonstration.REF As Straight Talk on Evidence puts it, “even a well-conducted RCT with blockbuster findings…generally does not provide a sufficient basis for widespread program implementation; there is a good chance that the program would not produce the hoped-for effects if implemented in new jurisdictions.”REF
Fourth, even in the unlikely event that a highly successful, replicable model is found, it is unlikely that a social program sector will readily “retool” to follow the model. Change is difficult, and replicating the success of one model suggests that many existing organizations, skills, and workers are unsuccessful and should be replaced or reformed. Bureaucratic inertia, historic ties, institutional ethos, and the instinct for organizational self-preservation all bolster the status quo. “Replicating a new model” often means little more than inserting a new set of buzzwords into the next grant application.
Fifth, even if the effort at replication is sincere, the “evidence-based” paradigm at best establishes broad programmatic guidance within a service sector. But the paradigm does not assess the thousands of individual service providers and therefore cannot separate “gems from lemons” at the specific provider level.
The Hawaii Opportunity Probation with Enforcement (HOPE) program, for example, had initial positive findings that did not carry over to the subsequent expansion. HOPE was a probation program that was found to have a significant effect on recidivism: Participants had a 55 percent reduction in rearrests in the 12 months following release.REF Based on this evidence, the program was quickly replicated and expanded to 28 locations in four other states (Arkansas, Massachusetts, Oregon, and Texas). However, the National Institute of Justice later commissioned another randomized controlled trial of the expansion programs and found far less effect.REF
Another example is the Maternal, Infant, and Early Childhood Home Visiting (MIECHV) program for vulnerable mothers that has been widely acclaimed as evidence-based. Congress authorized the program in 2010, despite the finding of a 2004 meta-analysis of home visitation programs that overall outcomes were not achieved.REF As of June 2017, HHS determined that 18 individual services were “evidenced-based.”REF The program currently expends $400 million a year to fund those services.REF However, in 2019, HHS found in its first early evaluation of program effectiveness that there was little difference in outcomes between the treatment and control groups: “No outcome area stands out as one where home visiting programs had large effects.”REF
Sixth, the third key attribute of the performance management model is the requirement for randomized controlled trialsREF and third-party evaluations.REF However, the best application of the scientific gold standard analysis of federal programs’ data still indicates that the social programs are not achieving measurable impacts for participants.REF As summarized in a 2018 review of the 13 known large RCTs of federal programs, “Eleven of the 13 RCTs found that the programs produced either no significant positive effects on the key targeted outcomes or small positive effects that dissipated shortly after participants completed the program.”REF
One social program with a large RCT analysis is the Teen Pregnancy Prevention (TPP) program. TPP is a federal grant program that, pursuant to reauthorization and reform in 2009, should be distributing 75 percent of its funds to “evidence-based” approaches. Analysis of TPP’s grants from 2010–2014, however, reveals that only four of 24 funded models reduced teen pregnancy rates.REF
Like HOPE, MIECHV, and TPP, the Head Start program is another illustration of initial promise unsupported by subsequent RCT studies. Head Start is one of the longest-running programs designed to help underprivileged children. The more than $10 billion-per-year federal preschool program was founded as part of Lyndon B. Johnson’s 1964 War on Poverty and modeled on the promise of the small-scale Perry Preschool and Carolinian Abecedarian programs.REF A large-scale, rigorous study was required by Congress in 1998, and in October 2012, HHS released its comprehensive final report, which demonstrated that any advantages gained through Head Start are short-term and undetectable by the time a participant reaches the third grade.REF
It is a step in the right direction that policymakers and executive agencies began to collect and track data on outcomes for beneficiaries and that Congress began to require randomized controlled trials of major programs’ outcome measures. However, the available evidence shows that the key reforms of the performance measurement model generally have not produced results for vulnerable individuals.
The Social Impact Bond/Pay-for-Success Model
Over the past decade, there has been another evolution in social programs as policymakers sought provable and sustainable results in social programs. Social impact bonds (SIBs), as they are known in the United Kingdom, or pay-for-success programs, as they are known in the U.S., are models in which private investors fund up-front costs for social programs to innovate in interventions to assist vulnerable individuals.
In a major difference from both the open grant and performance management models, in this model, the government repays the private investor only after a predefined goal is achieved, sometimes with an additional financial return. This moves social programs from paying for services to paying only for predefined and measurable outcomes. Most pay-for-success models have these primary players: government (national, regional, or local); the private-sector up-front investor; a direct service provider; and a third-party evaluator. The private investors and service provider are financially entirely responsible for achieving the results for the intended beneficiaries.
Generally, pay-for-success programs to date have invested in criminal justice, homelessness, child welfare, early childhood education, and youth development programs. The “outcome” or success metric will vary by each of these interventions. In many of the youth-focused programs, the success of the social impact bond will be judged by whether they avoided common problems such as, for instance, achieving a reduction in recidivism—i.e., returning to incarceration—or realizing a reduction in the percentage of children who need special education in kindergarten.
As of July 2019, 132 known SIBs had been launched in 25 countries.REF The movement began in the United Kingdom just as the country began to search for alternative funding models to resource and transform its public welfare programs after the Great Recession and subsequent austerity measures.
One of the first SIBs ever funded was focused on recidivism within the criminal justice system. The Peterborough prison in eastern England created a SIB called One Service in 2011. The intervention was focused on prisoners who served terms of less than 12 months. The goal was to reduce recidivism by a target 10 percent and at least 7.5 percent among the recently released prisoners compared to a control group.REF The RAND Corporation evaluation showed an 8.4 percent reduction (but not the target 10 percent) in recidivism in the first cohort.REF
In the United States, the pay-for-success projects began as state initiatives, with the first launching in 2013. There are now 26 ongoing projects in 13 states. It takes years for many of these projects to be implemented and to demonstrate results, and most last a minimum of four years. Therefore, because many currently funded projects were launched in 2015 or later, most do not yet have outcome data. For that reason, the U.S. review is limited to projects with available data, and most cases still have only preliminary results.
Because the United States has a high recidivism rate (within three years, nearly half of all prisoners released in 2005 were imprisoned again),REF many U.S. pay-for-success projects are focused on lowering the recidivism rate. This includes the first U.S. project, the $9.6 million New York City Rikers Adolescent Behavioral Learning Experience (ABLE) program was begun in 2013 to reduce recidivism among 4,458 formerly incarcerated youth who were 16–18 years old. The project’s goal was a 10 percent reduction in the recidivism rate from the historical Rikers rate of 50 percent. A study published by the Vera Institute of Justice concluded that the project’s recidivism reduction was not statistically significant, and the initiative was ended in August 2015.REF
Other recidivism projects have been initiated, including a State of New York project funded with a $12 million U.S. Department of Labor grant to increase employment by five points and reduce recidivism by eight points among 2,000 formerly incarcerated individuals in Rochester and New York City, with services to be provided by the Center for Economic Opportunities.REF However, third-party evaluations for these projects are not yet publicly available.
Other early U.S. pay-for-success projects have concentrated on early education. Utah focused on low-income children with a $7 million project that funded preschool slots for three-year-old and four-year-old low-income children who were at risk of needing special education.REF The project began in 2013 for a seven-year period. In 2015, investors and the state reported that 99 percent of the first cohort of “at-risk” children in the Utah program had avoided special education and that $267,000 had been paid out to investors.REF However, some researchers cited concerns with the initial estimation of the number of children potentially needing special education.REF
Chicago funded another preschool pay-for-success program. The city appropriated $17 million for 2,600 slots across nine preschools for four-year-old low-income children.REF The project initially saw 4.38 percent of children needing special education programming in kindergarten, 1.73 percentage points lower than the cohort’s comparison group.REF Investors were paid $9,100 plus interest for every child in the first cohort who did not need special education.REF
The first federal pay-for-success initiative, the Social Impact Partnerships to Pay for Results Act (SIPPRA), was included in the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2018.REF The act gave $100 million to the Department of the Treasury to pay for feasibility analysis and pay-for-success projects across the U.S. Of that total, $66 million will directly reimburse outcome payments. With half of the funds set aside for projects that directly benefit children.REF The 2019 Notice of Funding Availability outlines 21 options for “social benefit,” and participants must demonstrate both the social benefit and federal, state, or local government savings.REF The goals identified in the SIPPRA program currently have alternate federal funding. These projects are a fraction of overall expenditures when compared to similar federal governmental programs.
The key positive aspects of this model are that the goals and measurement (usually a singular measure) of the alternative funding approach are defined at the outset. Further, the goals are evaluated by a third-party evaluator. In addition, the private-sector investor and direct service provider are compensated only if they achieve the predefined goals.
However, pay-for-success models use new funds instead of drawing from the federal funds already appropriated to existing social programs that serve the same purpose. This means that the model is not transforming the underlying programs and the bulk of federal funding directed toward capacity-building. The small scale of pay-for-success projects is also necessarily limited to single experimental project sites and therefore subject to the “single-instance fallacy.”REF Because of the limited number of pay-for-success projects, the active projects are testing one service method out of hundreds of service options with similar goals. They are not able to show whether the success is a statistical fluke or due to the unique circumstances of the project site.
A New Paradigm: The Pay-for-Outcomes Model
The current evidence-based paradigm within social programs is inadequate. Few programs are found to work, those that do work usually have modest impacts, and the rare successful programs typically cannot be replicated. Running social programs with few if any expected results is hard on the taxpayer and likely to generate despair and alienation among recipients who deserve better.
What can be done? The answer is a pay-for-outcomes system built around clear principles.
Policymakers should transform federal social programs by rewarding providers directly for a clear and verifiable capacity-building outcome in the lives of vulnerable individuals. After nearly two decades of performance management and pay-for-success models, policymakers should combine the best features of these reforms by implementing the pay-for-outcomes model. The pay-for-outcomes model would be applied to entire federal social programs so that contracts are awarded to direct service providers only on the basis of their ability to achieve positive and clear-cut behavioral changes in the lives of vulnerable individuals, based on third-party verification of concrete outcomes as specified at the beginning of the project.
Because direct service providers would be awarded annual contracts only for predetermined measurable effects, paying for outcomes for individuals would ensure that direct service providers are either rewarded or held responsible for their effectiveness in producing positive changes in the lives of vulnerable individuals. With this responsibility, programs would be empowered to focus on responding to the distinctive needs of the individuals they serve. This payment model would weed out providers who are not achieving results for vulnerable individuals. Service providers that did not achieve the outcome predetermined by policymakers would not be awarded subsequent contracts.
Unlike the pay-for-success model, which involves small-scale experiments outside of and in addition to the regular program funding stream, the pay-for-outcomes model would redirect the billions in currently appropriated federal funds for social programs. Direct service organizations that already participate in these social programs would be able to continue their work, but in subsequent years, contracts would be renewed based only on the ability of these service providers to produce individual outcomes in a cost-effective manner.
In the pay-for-outcomes model, policymakers would finally have solid evidence that programs either are or are not working. Without evidence of positive outcomes, service providers would not be paid, and this would give them a strong incentive to prove that outcomes are not only measured, but actually achieved.
Finally, the pay-for-outcomes model gives service providers on the ground both freedom and responsibility. Those closest to human problems are in the best position to address the complexities of those problems. Instead of imposing a handful of allegedly effective models, the pay-for-outcomes model encourages innovation and allows people to apply their intelligence and intuition to meet the on-the-ground situation. The pay-for-outcomes principle also requires that service providers be financially responsible, evaluated based on clear outcomes, and rewarded only for success.
New York City Contracting. A successful example of the pay-for-outcomes approach is found in the welfare reforms initiated by Mayor Rudy Giuliani in New York City.REF In 1999, the Giuliani administration replaced the standard fee-for-service contracts for job placement/training organizations with pay-for-outcomes contracts. The contractors responded to the financial incentives embodied in the new contracts quickly and effectively. For example, the new contracts prioritized increasing the number of job placements (i.e., new hires) among recipients; within a year, the number of job placements generated by the contractors doubled.REF
A few years later, revised pay-for-outcomes contracts were issued under the administration of Mayor Michael Bloomberg. These revised contracts provided larger financial rewards for job retention relative to job placements. The contractors again responded to these incentives, and the average share of clients who retained jobs for more than 90 days was as much as 198 percent higher under the new contracts compared to the old.REF
Under the system in both administrations, potential providers were required to bid for contracts. The bidding process generated financial pressure that weeded out the less efficient providers. The original set of 15 prime contractors in 1999 was pruned to seven by 2010.REF
Five Policy Principles for Implementation of Pay-for-Outcomes
Five key policy principles are necessary for successful implementation of a pay-for-outcomes model.
In order to avoid this pitfall, policymakers must identify the particular outcome they are seeking among recipients at the outset. This model should be implemented in social programs with either a control group or a known benchmark for comparison. For instance, a prison recidivism project would be awarded a contract based on the number of beneficiaries who avoided prison; a drug treatment program would be rewarded for the number of beneficiaries with clean drug tests for 12 months; an employment and training program would be judged by the number of beneficiaries who obtained a job and the average compensation of such employment; and an education program could be measured objectively by increases in high school completion or improved math and reading scores.
To achieve better outcomes, providers must have a financial stake in the success of their operations. They must be, at least in part, fiscally accountable for their own success or failure. Government financial rewards should be contingent on the outcomes achieved, and the provider should bear at least part of the cost of ineffective and failed services.
Similarly, pay-for-outcomes contracts can also be established between different levels of government. The government organization with funding authority could distribute those funds through pay-for-outcomes contracts with other government entities rather than through open-ended grants. For example, the federal government could channel its current social funds through pay-for-outcomes contracts with state and local governments. The state and local agencies receiving federal funds should be rewarded for achieving outcomes but should bear a greater share of the financial burden when programs are ineffective. Increasing the fiscal accountability of the agencies delivering the programs should incentivize and invigorate program improvement.
-
Set clear quantitative outcome measures for service providers. The pay-for-outcomes model requires a clear, concrete, and quantifiable outcome measure in the lives of those the program is intended to help. Each individual service provider should be measured according to the concrete outcomes obtained for its clientele. The desired outcomes would be defined, quantified, and objectively measured using reliable sources independent from the service provider. All providers would be under contract and paid for clear results. These payments could take place on a quarterly basis, based either on the total number of outcomes or on outcomes above an assumed nonintervention baseline.
Complex measurements like benefit/cost analysis, while useful for some purposes, should be avoided as primary outcome measures because they involve complex calculations with many hidden assumptions that can easily be manipulated to achieve desired results. Even accurately reported data and well-conducted randomized control trials tend to track a wide array of data outcomes, and this can result in selective reporting of outcome findings. In some studies, researchers identify encouraging outcomes by focusing on data points that demonstrate positive effects while disregarding negative data points.REF
-
Provide payment for outcomes, not services provided or savings achieved. Contractors would provide services but would be paid, wholly or in part, not for the services delivered but for the objective and measured outcomes achieved.REF For example, providers could be paid for the number persons actively employed and average wages received or based on the percent of reentering inmates who were not arrested or incarcerated in the three years after release. Multiple measures could be used within a single program.
Unlike the pay-for-success models operating in the states—and even at the federal level in the SIPPRA program—the measurement cannot be whether the program saved government money. The pay-for-outcomes model seeks concrete results in terms of building positive social outcomes and the capacity of individuals for self-support. Taxpayer savings may still follow when, for example, individuals become more likely to work or avoid reincarceration, but such savings would be unconnected to the flow of funds between government and program operators.
-
Place multiple service providers in competition. Under a pay-for-outcomes system, service providers would be held financially accountable for their own success or failure. In addition, funding agencies should establish pay-for-outcomes contracts with multiple contractors who would be placed in competition with each other.REF The contractors could be either nonprofit or for-profit organizations.
Contractors would not be allowed to select their own clients, as this would lead to choosing clients who are likely to succeed while ignoring more difficult clients. Some recent outcome studies have demonstrated this risk by highlighting subgroups with positive outcomes as opposed to the full sample of participants, misrepresenting program results.REF Instead, a central administrator would allocate a fixed share of clients to each service provider as fairly as possible. The providers would then compete to achieve better outcomes for their roster of clients.
Service providers would be free to innovate and devise their own approach to achieving the desired outcomes. Creative approaches and diligent management are likely to flourish because the prosperity and survival of the organization depend on achieving successful outcomes.
-
Shift funding automatically from low to high performers. After the early years’ implementation, successful programs will begin to compete against each other comparing best individual outcome results and lowest cost per result. The most successful will be awarded the highest portion of the subsequent years’ funding automatically. This competition can also lead to clear and continued improvement over time. Funding would automatically be shifted from low performers to high performers. Effective providers who demonstrated better actual outcomes would not only receive more funds for their achievements. Over time, they would also increase their “market share” while that of inefficient providers would automatically shrink.
Providers who produced few measured outcomes would lose money and quickly drop out of the program. When this occurred, funds would not be cut; instead, they would automatically be shifted to the more efficient service providers.
All contracts would be renegotiated periodically. Contractors would bid for the price they sought to be paid for each unit or numeric goal achieved (number of persons employed, etc.). Inefficient providers would not gain contracts, and contractors that did not achieve targets would not be renewed. Lower bidders would receive contracts and a greater share of future clients, especially if they meet program goals. This process would reduce the unit cost of outcomes, and the savings achieved would be redirected into expanded or enhanced services.
Future clients would benefit as funds are automatically shifted from ineffective high-cost service providers to more effective lower-cost providers and services in the community are expanded. Pay-for-outcomes is an exercise in improving the lives of vulnerable Americans. Budget savings for taxpayers are a byproduct of prioritizing these human outcomes.
-
Continue RCT evidence-based evaluations. To a considerable degree, the process described above is self-rectifying. Efficiency is automatically increased as funds are shifted from ineffective high-cost providers to more effective low-cost providers. Nonetheless, periodic reassessment of the overall social impact of the spending program would be critical. This could be accomplished by performing recurring random assignment evaluations on various providers within the program. RCT evaluations would be particularly important for ascertaining baseline outcomes that would occur in the absence of the overall program intervention.
Current Federal Programs Where Pay-for-Outcomes Should Be Implemented
Policymakers should begin to implement this model in social programs that have the best potential for the measurement of clear results. The following are some of the strongest candidates for implementation of the pay-for-outcomes model.
-
Employment and Training (E&T). Employment and training programs are particularly ripe for reform because of their continually documented lack of success despite long-standing congressional efforts to reform them. There are 43 employment and training programs across nine federal agencies, primarily at the Departments of Labor, Education, and Health and Human Services.REF They cover all federal expenditures to help beneficiaries build skills and identify and obtain employment. According to the Council of Economic Advisers, “[a]ggregate spending on these programs totaled $18.9 billion in 2019 alone.”REF
Although programs were reformed most recently in 2014 with the intention of funds being distributed according to the evidenced-based model, that reform has not demonstrated successful outcomes for recipients.REF Congress should take a further step and transform E&T programs to measure clear outcomes for beneficiaries, principally employment attained and earnings achieved.
-
Substance Abuse Treatment. The U.S. struggle against drug addiction spans decades. In 2018, more than 67,000 Americans died from drug overdoses—with synthetic opioids being the main driver.REF The federal government expended more than $10.5 billion on substance abuse treatment in FY 2017.REF
The Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration (SAMHSA) has authority over the main block grant, called the Substance Abuse Block Grants. In addition to this block grant, the previously discussed Substance Abuse Prevention and Treatment (SAPT) Block Grant, and other SAMSHA substance abuse grants, the 21st Century Cures Act passed by Congress in 2016 allocates nearly $500 million per year through the Opioid State Targeted Response (STR) program, which is distributed to all states and territories based on the degree of their opioid addiction problem.REF
While these programs may increase access to treatment, there is little evidence of their effect on other outcomes. Most of these programs collect evidence on four performance metrics, including sobriety rates immediately after release from treatment, completion of the program, client interviews, and internal studies. None of these data sets will tell the public whether medium-term or long-term sobriety was achieved. The true measurement that Congress should set for these programs is whether sobriety (established, for instance, by clean drug tests) is maintained for a set period (12 months) after treatment.
-
Recidivism Reduction. With the U.S. historical recidivism rate of nearly 50 percent and the possibility for a clear outcome metric, social programs that focus on recidivism should be a priority for reform according to the pay-for-outcomes model.REF In early 2020, almost 2.3 million Americans, including approximately 52,000 minors, were incarcerated in federal, state, and local prisons and jails.REF In FY 2015, the Department of Justice distributed $68 million in recidivism reduction grants.REF
Reducing recidivism is clearly a goal of many federal programs outside of those funded through the Department of Justice, and there is some evidence that mental health or substance abuse programs may have promise, but there is no updated, systematic evidence that these programs work at large.REF “Across the country,” according to a 2019 study, “government agencies and non-profit organizations operate a wide variety of programs designed to improve prisoner reentry outcomes. Though these programs are well-intentioned, few have undergone rigorous evaluation of their effects.”REF
While Congress and administrators of these programs have relied heavily on evidence-based services that in some cases may deter reincarceration, a reformed recidivism program measurement would include payment based on whether the individual avoids reentry for from one to three years.
-
Federal Grants to Improve Self-Sufficiency. The social program block grants that are currently distributed according to an open grant model—the Social Services Block Grant (SSBG), Community Services Block Grant (CSBG), and Community Development Block Grant (CDBG)—are clear examples of the need for action by Congress. As noted, these programs may have commendable goals, but they do not produce quantifiable results for their intended beneficiaries.
Congress should separate and define the goals of these programs. In the SSBG, for instance, Congress would have to clarify the statutory goals. If the new goal was to provide for foster care, then that goal and the corresponding measurement should be defined. A new measurable goal could be a shorter time frame during which children remain in foster care without permanency.REF Likewise, in the CSBG, Congress would have to define and measure goals—in this case whether an individual achieves self-sufficiency and no longer depends on key federal transfer programs. Finally, in the CDBG, Congress should limit funding to service providers who find permanent (at least 12 months) housing (ideally nongovernmental housing) for low-income families.
Conclusion
Social programs aim to open transformational pathways for vulnerable individuals. They seek to help the unemployed obtain meaningful work, the formerly incarcerated to be rehabilitated, and those trapped in addiction to be freed from dependence. They aspire to help low-income and vulnerable Americans build their capacity and truly improve their lives and well-being.
The federal government has made bold promises with good intentions, spending billions on social programs for individuals who are vulnerable to poverty and dependence on government safety-net programs to achieve self-sufficiency. But today’s social programs are not succeeding, partly because the design of current programs does not hold service providers accountable for delivering the results that policymakers, the public, and—most importantly—program beneficiaries desire. The recipients of these services and their families deserve better, and simply expanding funding for current programs that lack the necessary accountability to deliver those desired results is wholly inadequate to the task.
Instead, federal policymakers should transform social programs by paying directly for positive outcomes. A pay-for-outcomes system built around clear principles would transform federal social programs by rewarding providers directly for clear and verifiable outcomes in the lives of vulnerable individuals. This model would deliver systemic change in social programs and finally deliver the results that policymakers seek and vulnerable individuals deserve.
Leslie Ford is a Visiting Fellow in Domestic Policy Studies, of the Institute for Family, Community, and Opportunity, at The Heritage Foundation. Robert Rector is a Senior Research Fellow in Domestic Policy Studies.